United States – Certain Country of
Origin Labelling (COOL) Requirements
Recourse to Article 21.5 of the DSU by Canada and
Mexico
reports of the panel
Addendum
This addendum
contains Annexes A to C to the Reports of the Panel to be
found in documents WT/DS384/RW and
WT/DS386/RW.
_______________
LIST OF ANNEXES
ANNEX A
Working
Procedures of The Panel
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex A-1
|
Working Procedures of the Panel (DS384) as revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-2
|
Annex A-2
|
Working Procedures of the Panel (DS386) as revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-6
|
Annex A-3
|
Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the Panel (DS384) as
revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-10
|
Annex A-4
|
Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the Panel (DS386) as
revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-11
|
Annex A-5
|
Procedures of the Panel concerning business confidential information
(DS384)
|
A-12
|
Annex A-6
|
Procedures of the Panel concerning business confidential information
(DS386)
|
A-13
|
ANNEX
B
Arguments
Of The Parties
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex B-1
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Canada
|
B-2
|
Annex B-2
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Mexico
|
B-14
|
Annex B-3
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the United States
|
B-27
|
ANNEX C
Arguments
of the Third Parties
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex C-1
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of Brazil
|
C-2
|
Annex C-2
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of China
|
C-4
|
Annex C-3
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of Colombia
|
C-7
|
Annex C-4
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of the European Union
|
C-10
|
Annex C-5
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of India
|
C-15
|
Annex C-6
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of Japan
|
C-18
|
Annex C-7
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of the Republic of Korea
|
C-24
|
Annex C-8
|
Integrated executive
summary of the arguments of New Zealand
|
C-26
|
ANNEX A
Working
Procedures of the Panel
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex A-1
|
Working Procedures of the Panel (DS384) as revised on
21 January 2014
|
A-2
|
Annex A-2
|
Working Procedures of the Panel (DS386) as revised on
21 January 2014
|
A-6
|
Annex A-3
|
Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the
Panel (DS384) as revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-10
|
Annex A-4
|
Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the
Panel (DS386) as revised on 21 January 2014
|
A-11
|
Annex A-5
|
Procedures of the Panel concerning business
confidential information (DS384)
|
A-12
|
Annex A-6
|
Procedures of the Panel concerning business
confidential information (DS386)
|
A-13
|
ANNEX
A-1
working
procedures of the panel (ds384)
Adopted on
25 October 2013 and revised on 21 January 2014
1. In
its proceedings, the Panel shall follow the relevant provisions of the
Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes
(DSU). In addition, the following Working Procedures shall apply.
General
2. The
deliberations of the Panel and the documents submitted to it shall be kept
confidential. Nothing in the DSU or in these Working Procedures shall preclude
a party to the dispute (hereafter "party") from disclosing
statements of its own positions to the public. Members shall treat as
confidential information submitted by another Member to the Panel which the
submitting Member has designated as confidential. Where a party submits a
confidential version of its written submissions to the Panel, it shall also,
upon request of a Member, provide a non-confidential summary of the information
contained in its submissions that could be disclosed to the public.
The Panel may adopt special procedures concerning Business Confidential Information after consulting the parties.
3. The
parties, and Members having notified their interest in the dispute to the
Dispute Settlement Body in accordance with Article 10 of the DSU
(hereafter "third parties"), shall be present at the meetings only
when invited by the Panel to appear before it. The Panel may open its meetings
with the parties to the public, subject to appropriate procedures to be adopted
by the Panel after consulting the parties.
4. Each
party and third party has the right to determine the composition of its own
delegation when meeting with the Panel. Each party and third party shall have
responsibility for all members of its own delegation and shall ensure that each
member of such delegation acts in accordance with the DSU and these Working
Procedures, particularly with regard to the confidentiality of the proceedings.
Submissions
5. Before
the substantive meeting of the Panel with the parties, each party shall
transmit to the Panel a first written submission, and subsequently a written
rebuttal, in which it presents the facts of the case and its arguments, and
counter-arguments, respectively, in accordance with the timetable adopted by
the Panel.
6. A
party shall submit any request for a preliminary ruling at the earliest possible
opportunity and in any event no later than in its first written submission to
the Panel. If Canada requests such a ruling, the United States shall
submit its response to the request in its first written submission. If the United States
requests such a ruling, Canada shall submit its response to the request prior
to the substantive meeting of the Panel, at a time to be determined by the
Panel in light of the request. Exceptions to this procedure shall be granted
upon a showing of good cause.
7. Each
party shall submit all factual evidence to the Panel no later than during the
substantive meeting, except with respect to evidence necessary for purposes of
rebuttal, answers to questions or comments on answers provided by the other
party. Exceptions to this procedure shall be granted upon a showing of good
cause. Where such exception has been granted, the Panel shall accord the other
party a period of time for comment, as appropriate, on any new factual evidence
submitted after the substantive meeting.
8. Where
the original language of exhibits is not a WTO working language, the submitting
party or third party shall submit a translation into the WTO working language
of the submission at the same time. The Panel may grant reasonable extensions
of time for the translation of such exhibits upon a showing of good cause. Any
objection as to the accuracy of a translation should be raised promptly in
writing, no later than the next filing or meeting (whichever occurs earlier)
following the submission which contains the translation in question. Any
objection shall be accompanied by a detailed explanation of the grounds of
objection and an alternative translation.
9. In
order to facilitate the work of the Panel, each party and third party is
invited to make its submissions in accordance with the WTO Editorial Guide for
Panel Submissions attached as Annex 1.
10. To
facilitate the maintenance of the record, and maximize the clarity of
submissions, each party and third party shall sequentially number its exhibits
throughout the course of the compliance proceedings. For example, exhibits
submitted by Canada could be numbered CDA‑1, CDA‑2, etc. If the last exhibit in
connection with the first submission was numbered CDA‑5, the first exhibit
of the next submission thus would be numbered CDA‑6. The first time a
party or third party submits to the Panel an exhibit that corresponds to an
exhibit submitted in the original panel proceedings, the party or third party
submitting such exhibit shall also identify the number of the original exhibit
in the original panel proceedings.
Questions
11. The
Panel may at any time pose questions to the parties and third parties, orally
in the course of the substantive meeting or in writing.
Substantive
meeting
12. Each
party shall provide to the Panel the list of members of its delegation in
advance of the meeting with the Panel and no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time)
on the previous working day.
13. The
substantive meeting of the Panel shall be conducted as follows:
a. The Panel shall invite Canada to make an
opening statement to present its case first. Subsequently, the Panel shall
invite the United States to present its point of view. Before taking the
floor, each party shall provide the Panel and other participants at the meeting
with a provisional written version of its statement. In the event that
interpretation is needed, each party shall provide additional copies to the
interpreters. Each party shall make available to the Panel and the other party
the final version of its statement, preferably at the end of the meeting, and
in any event no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the first working
day following the meeting.
b. After the conclusion of the statements, the
Panel shall give each party the opportunity to ask questions or make comments,
through the Panel. Each party shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by the Panel, any questions to the other party to which it wishes to
receive a response in writing. Each party shall be invited to respond in
writing to the other party's questions within a deadline to be determined by
the Panel.
c. The Panel may subsequently pose questions to
the parties. The Panel shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by it, any questions to the parties to which it wishes to receive a
response in writing. Each party shall be invited to respond in writing to such
questions within a deadline to be determined by the Panel. The Panel's written
questions to the parties and each party's written answers to questions after
the substantive meeting with the Panel shall be made available to all third
parties.
d. Once the questioning has concluded, the Panel
shall afford each party an opportunity to present a brief closing statement,
with Canada presenting its statement first, followed by the United States.
Third
parties
14. The
Panel shall invite each third party to transmit to the Panel a written
submission prior to the substantive meeting of the Panel with the parties, in
accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel.
15. All
third parties may be present during the entirety of the substantive meeting
with the parties. During this meeting, third parties may, at the invitation of
the Panel, ask questions to the parties or the other third parties. The parties
and the other third parties, however, have no obligation to respond to these
questions.
16. Each
third party shall also be invited to present its views orally during a session
of the substantive meeting, set aside for that purpose. Each third party shall
provide to the Panel the list of members of its delegation in advance of this
session and no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the previous working day.
17. The
third party session shall be conducted as follows:
a. All third parties may be present during the
entirety of this session.
b. The Panel shall first hear the arguments of
the third parties in alphabetical order. Third parties present at the
third-party session and intending to present their views orally at that
session, shall provide the Panel, the parties and other third parties with
provisional written versions of their statements before they take the floor. In
the event that interpretation is needed, each third party shall provide
additional copies to the interpreters. Third parties shall make available to
the Panel, the parties and other third parties the final versions of their
statements, preferably at the end of the session, and in any event no later
than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the first working day following the session.
c. After the third parties have made their
statements, the parties may be given the opportunity, through the Panel, to ask
the third parties questions for clarification on any matter raised in the third
parties' submissions or statements. Each party shall send in writing, within a
timeframe to be determined by the Panel, any questions to a third party to
which it wishes to receive a response in writing.
d. The Panel may subsequently pose questions to
the third parties. The Panel shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by it, any questions to the third parties to which it wishes to
receive a response in writing. Each third party shall be invited to respond in
writing to such questions within a deadline to be determined by the Panel.
Descriptive
part
18. The
description of the arguments of the parties and third parties in the
descriptive part of the Panel report shall consist of executive summaries
provided by the parties and third parties, which shall be annexed as addenda to
the report. These executive summaries shall not in any way serve as a
substitute for the submissions of the parties and third parties in the Panel's
examination of the case.
19. Each
party shall submit an executive summary of the facts and arguments as presented
to the Panel in its written submissions and oral statements, in accordance with
the timetable adopted by the Panel. This executive summary may also include a
summary of responses to questions. The Panel will not summarize in the
descriptive part of its report, or annex to its report, the parties' responses
to questions. The executive summary provided by each party shall not exceed
15 pages.
20. Each
third party shall submit an executive summary of its arguments as presented in
its written submission and statement in accordance with the timetable adopted
by the Panel. This summary may also include a summary of responses to
questions, where relevant. The executive summary to be provided by each third
party shall not exceed 6 pages.
Interim review
21. Following
issuance of the interim report, each party may submit a written request to
review precise aspects of the interim report and request a further meeting with
the Panel in accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel. The right to
request such a meeting shall be exercised no later than at the time the written
request for review is submitted.
22. In
the event that no further meeting with the Panel is requested, each party may
submit written comments on the other party's written request for review in
accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel. Such comments shall be
limited to commenting on the other party's written request for review.
23. The
interim report, as well as the final report prior to its official circulation,
shall be kept strictly confidential and shall not be disclosed.
Service of
documents
24. The
following procedures regarding service of documents shall apply:
a. Each party and third party shall submit all
documents to the Panel by filing them with the DS Registry (office No.
2047).
b. Each party and third party shall file three
paper copies of all documents it submits to the Panel. When exhibits are
provided on CD‑ROMS/DVDs, three CD‑ROMS/DVDs and three paper copies of those
exhibits shall be filed. The DS Registrar shall stamp the documents with
the date and time of the filing. The paper version shall constitute the
official version for the purposes of the record of the dispute.
c. Each party and third party shall also provide
an electronic copy of all documents it submits to the Panel at the same time as
the paper versions, in Microsoft Word format, either on a CD-ROM, a DVD or as
an e-mail attachment. If the electronic copy is provided by e-mail, it should
be addressed to *****@wto.org, and cc'd to *****.*****@wto.org, to
*****.*****@wto.org, to *****.*****@wto.org, and to *****.*****@wto.org. If a
CD-ROM or DVD is provided, it shall be filed with the DS Registry.
d. Each party shall serve any document submitted
to the Panel directly on the other party. Each party shall, in addition, serve
on all third parties its written submissions in advance of the substantive
meeting with the Panel. Each third party shall serve any document submitted to
the Panel directly on the parties and all other third parties. Each party and
third party shall confirm, in writing, that copies have been served as required
at the time it provides each document to the Panel.
e. Each party and third party shall file its
documents with the DS Registry and serve copies on the other party (and third
parties where appropriate) by 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the due dates
established by the Panel.
f. The Panel shall provide the parties with an
electronic version of the descriptive part, the interim report and the final
report, as well as of other documents as appropriate. When the Panel transmits
to the parties or third parties both paper and electronic versions of a
document, the paper version shall constitute the official version for the
purposes of the record of the dispute.
25. The
Panel reserves the right to modify these procedures at any time following
consultations with the parties.
ANNEX A-2
working
procedures of the panel (DS386)
Adopted on
25 October 2013 and revised on 21 January 2014
1. In
its proceedings, the Panel shall follow the relevant provisions of the
Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes
(DSU). In addition, the following Working Procedures shall apply.
General
2. The
deliberations of the Panel and the documents submitted to it shall be kept
confidential. Nothing in the DSU or in these Working Procedures shall preclude
a party to the dispute (hereafter "party") from disclosing
statements of its own positions to the public. Members shall treat as
confidential information submitted by another Member to the Panel which the
submitting Member has designated as confidential. Where a party submits a
confidential version of its written submissions to the Panel, it shall also,
upon request of a Member, provide a non-confidential summary of the information
contained in its submissions that could be disclosed to the public.
The Panel may adopt special procedures concerning Business Confidential Information after consulting the parties.
3. The
parties, and Members having notified their interest in the dispute to the
Dispute Settlement Body in accordance with Article 10 of the DSU
(hereafter "third parties"), shall be present at the meetings
only when invited by the Panel to appear before it. The Panel may open its
meetings with the parties to the public, subject to appropriate procedures to
be adopted by the Panel after consulting the parties.
4. Each
party and third party has the right to determine the composition of its own
delegation when meeting with the Panel. Each party and third party shall have
responsibility for all members of its own delegation and shall ensure that each
member of such delegation acts in accordance with the DSU and these Working
Procedures, particularly with regard to the confidentiality of the proceedings.
Submissions
5. Before
the substantive meeting of the Panel with the parties, each party shall
transmit to the Panel a first written submission, and subsequently a written
rebuttal, in which it presents the facts of the case and its arguments, and
counter-arguments, respectively, in accordance with the timetable adopted by
the Panel.
6. A
party shall submit any request for a preliminary ruling at the earliest
possible opportunity and in any event no later than in its first written
submission to the Panel. If Mexico requests such a ruling, the United States
shall submit its response to the request in its first written submission. If
the United States requests such a ruling, Mexico shall submit its response
to the request prior to the substantive meeting of the Panel, at a time to be
determined by the Panel in light of the request. Exceptions to this procedure
shall be granted upon a showing of good cause.
7. Each
party shall submit all factual evidence to the Panel no later than during the
substantive meeting, except with respect to evidence necessary for purposes of
rebuttal, answers to questions or comments on answers provided by the other
party. Exceptions to this procedure shall be granted upon a showing of good
cause. Where such exception has been granted, the Panel shall accord the other
party a period of time for comment, as appropriate, on any new factual evidence
submitted after the substantive meeting.
8. Where
the original language of exhibits is not a WTO working language, the submitting
party or third party shall submit a translation into the WTO working language
of the submission at the same time. The Panel may grant reasonable extensions
of time for the translation of such exhibits upon a showing of good cause. Any
objection as to the accuracy of a translation should be raised promptly in
writing, no later than the next filing or meeting (whichever occurs earlier)
following the submission which contains the translation in question. Any
objection shall be accompanied by a detailed explanation of the grounds of
objection and an alternative translation.
9. In
order to facilitate the work of the Panel, each party and third party is
invited to make its submissions in accordance with the WTO Editorial Guide for
Panel Submissions attached as Annex 1.
10. To
facilitate the maintenance of the record, and maximize the clarity of submissions,
each party and third party shall sequentially number its exhibits throughout
the course of the compliance proceedings. For example, exhibits submitted by
Mexico could be numbered MEX‑1, MEX‑2, etc. If the last exhibit in connection
with the first submission was numbered MEX‑5, the first exhibit of the
next submission thus would be numbered MEX‑6. The first time a party or
third party submits to the Panel an exhibit that corresponds to an exhibit
submitted in the original panel proceedings, the party or third party
submitting such exhibit shall also identify the number of the original exhibit
in the original panel proceedings.
Questions
11. The
Panel may at any time pose questions to the parties and third parties, orally
in the course of the substantive meeting or in writing.
Substantive
meeting
12. Each
party shall provide to the Panel the list of members of its delegation in
advance of the meeting with the Panel and no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time)
on the previous working day.
13. The
substantive meeting of the Panel shall be conducted as follows:
a. The Panel shall invite Mexico to make an
opening statement to present its case first. Subsequently, the Panel shall
invite the United States to present its point of view. Before taking the
floor, each party shall provide the Panel and other participants at the meeting
with a provisional written version of its statement. In the event that
interpretation is needed, each party shall provide additional copies to the
interpreters. Each party shall make available to the Panel and the other party
the final version of its statement, preferably at the end of the meeting, and
in any event no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the first working
day following the meeting.
b. After the conclusion of the statements, the
Panel shall give each party the opportunity to ask questions or make comments,
through the Panel. Each party shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by the Panel, any questions to the other party to which it wishes to
receive a response in writing. Each party shall be invited to respond in
writing to the other party's questions within a deadline to be determined by
the Panel.
c. The Panel may subsequently pose questions to
the parties. The Panel shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by it, any questions to the parties to which it wishes to receive a
response in writing. Each party shall be invited to respond in writing to such
questions within a deadline to be determined by the Panel. The Panel's written questions
to the parties and each party's written answers to questions after the
substantive meeting with the Panel shall be made available to all third
parties.
d. Once the questioning has concluded, the Panel
shall afford each party an opportunity to present a brief closing statement,
with Mexico presenting its statement first, followed by the United States.
Third
parties
14. The
Panel shall invite each third party to transmit to the Panel a written
submission prior to the substantive meeting of the Panel with the parties, in
accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel.
15. All
third parties may be present during the entirety of the substantive meeting
with the parties. During this meeting, third parties may, at the invitation of
the Panel, ask questions to the parties or the other third parties. The parties
and the other third parties, however, have no obligation to respond to these
questions.
16. Each
third party shall also be invited to present its views orally during a session
of the substantive meeting, set aside for that purpose. Each third party shall
provide to the Panel the list of members of its delegation in advance of this
session and no later than 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the previous working day.
17. The
third party session shall be conducted as follows:
a. All third parties may be present during the
entirety of this session.
b. The Panel shall first hear the arguments of
the third parties in alphabetical order. Third parties present at the
third-party session and intending to present their views orally at that
session, shall provide the Panel, the parties and other third parties with
provisional written versions of their statements before they take the floor. In
the event that interpretation is needed, each third party shall provide additional
copies to the interpreters. Third parties shall make available to the Panel,
the parties and other third parties the final versions of their statements,
preferably at the end of the session, and in any event no later than 5.00 p.m.
(Geneva time) on the first working day following the session.
c. After the third parties have made their
statements, the parties may be given the opportunity, through the Panel, to ask
the third parties questions for clarification on any matter raised in the third
parties' submissions or statements. Each party shall send in writing, within a
timeframe to be determined by the Panel, any questions to a third party to
which it wishes to receive a response in writing.
d. The Panel may subsequently pose questions to
the third parties. The Panel shall send in writing, within a timeframe to be
determined by it, any questions to the third parties to which it wishes to
receive a response in writing. Each third party shall be invited to respond in
writing to such questions within a deadline to be determined by the Panel.
Descriptive
part
18. The
description of the arguments of the parties and third parties in the
descriptive part of the Panel report shall consist of executive summaries
provided by the parties and third parties, which shall be annexed as addenda to
the report. These executive summaries shall not in any way serve as a
substitute for the submissions of the parties and third parties in the Panel's
examination of the case.
19. Each
party shall submit an executive summary of the facts and arguments as presented
to the Panel in its written submissions and oral statements, in accordance with
the timetable adopted by the Panel. This executive summary may also include a
summary of responses to questions. The Panel will not summarize in the
descriptive part of its report, or annex to its report, the parties' responses
to questions. The executive summary provided by each party shall not exceed
15 pages.
20. Each
third party shall submit an executive summary of its arguments as presented in
its written submission and statement in accordance with the timetable adopted
by the Panel. This summary may also include a summary of responses to
questions, where relevant. The executive summary to be provided by each third
party shall not exceed 6 pages.
Interim review
21. Following
issuance of the interim report, each party may submit a written request to
review precise aspects of the interim report and request a further meeting with
the Panel in accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel. The right to
request such a meeting shall be exercised no later than at the time the written
request for review is submitted.
22. In
the event that no further meeting with the Panel is requested, each party may
submit written comments on the other party's written request for review in
accordance with the timetable adopted by the Panel. Such comments shall be
limited to commenting on the other party's written request for review.
23. The
interim report, as well as the final report prior to its official circulation,
shall be kept strictly confidential and shall not be disclosed.
Service of
documents
24. The
following procedures regarding service of documents shall apply:
a. Each party and third party shall submit all
documents to the Panel by filing them with the DS Registry (office No.
2047).
b. Each party and third party shall file three
paper copies of all documents it submits to the Panel. When exhibits are
provided on CD‑ROMS/DVDs, three CD‑ROMS/DVDs and three paper copies of those
exhibits shall be filed. The DS Registrar shall stamp the documents with
the date and time of the filing. The paper version shall constitute the
official version for the purposes of the record of the dispute.
c. Each party and third party shall also provide
an electronic copy of all documents it submits to the Panel at the same time as
the paper versions, in Microsoft Word format, either on a CD-ROM, a DVD or as
an e-mail attachment. If the electronic copy is provided by e-mail, it should
be addressed to *****@wto.org, and cc'd to *****.*****@wto.org, *****.*****@wto.org,
*****.*****@wto.org, and *****.*****@wto.org. If a CD-ROM or DVD is provided,
it shall be filed with the DS Registry.
d. Each party shall serve any document submitted
to the Panel directly on the other party. Each party shall, in addition, serve
on all third parties its written submissions in advance of the substantive
meeting with the Panel. Each third party shall serve any document submitted to
the Panel directly on the parties and all other third parties. Each party and
third party shall confirm, in writing, that copies have been served as required
at the time it provides each document to the Panel.
e. Each party and third party shall file its
documents with the DS Registry and serve copies on the other party (and third
parties where appropriate) by 5.00 p.m. (Geneva time) on the due dates
established by the Panel.
f. The Panel shall provide the parties with an
electronic version of the descriptive part, the interim report and the final
report, as well as of other documents as appropriate. When the Panel transmits
to the parties or third parties both paper and electronic versions of a
document, the paper version shall constitute the official version for the
purposes of the record of the dispute.
25. The
Panel reserves the right to modify these procedures at any time following
consultations with the parties.
ANNEX
A-3
Procedures
for an open substantive meeting of the Panel[1] (DS384)
Adopted on
28 October 2013 and revised on 21 January 2014
1. The Panel shall hold a joint substantive
meeting in DS384 and DS386.
2. Subject to the availability of suitable WTO
meeting rooms, the Panel will start its substantive meeting, on 18-19 February
2014, with a session with the parties open to the public. At that session, each
party will be asked to make an opening statement. After the parties have made
their statements, they will be given the opportunity to pose questions to the
other party or make comments on the other party's statement. The Panel may pose
any questions or make any comments during such session.
The parties will also have an opportunity to make their closing statement
during the session open to the public.
3. To
the extent that the Panel or any party considers it necessary, the Panel will
also hold a session with the parties not open to public observation during
which the parties will be allowed to make additional statements or comments,
and pose questions, that involve business confidential information. The Panel
may also pose questions during such a session.
4. In
addition to its sessions with the parties, at the substantive meeting the Panel
will also hold a separate session with the third parties. The Panel will start
the third party session by opening a portion of this session to the public. At
this portion of the third party session, any third party wishing to make its
oral statement in a public session shall do so. Following the third party open
session, the Panel will proceed to a third party closed session during which
any other third party shall make its oral statement. At each of these third
party open or closed sessions, after the third parties' statements, the Panel
or any party may pose questions to any third party or make comments concerning
these statements. Third parties may also ask questions to the parties or other
third parties at the invitation of the Panel; however, the parties and the
other third parties have no obligation to respond to these questions by third
parties.
5. The
following persons will be admitted into the meeting room during all sessions of
the Panel's substantive meeting, whether open or closed to the public:
– the
members of the Panel;
– all
members of the delegations of the parties to DS384 and DS386;
– all
members of the delegations of the third parties to DS384 and DS386; and
– WTO
Secretariat staff assisting the Panel.
6. No
person shall disclose any business confidential information at any session open
to the public.
7. WTO
Members and Observers and the public may observe the Panel's sessions that are
open to the public by means of a real time closed-circuit television broadcast
to a separate viewing room. The broadcasts will be open to officials of WTO
Members and Observers upon presentation of their official badges. Accredited
journalists and representatives of relevant non-governmental organizations may
indicate to the Secretariat their interest in attending the broadcasts
(Information and External Relations Division). Members of the general public
will be invited to register their interest in attending each broadcast via the
WTO website, by close of business on 7 February 2014.
ANNEX
A-4
Procedures
for an open substantive meeting of the Panel[2] (DS386)
Adopted on
28 October 2013 and revised on 21 January 2014
1. The Panel shall hold a joint substantive
meeting in DS386 and DS384.
2. Subject to the availability of suitable WTO
meeting rooms, the Panel will start its substantive meeting, on 18-19 February
2014, with a session with the parties open to the public. At that session, each party will be asked to
make an opening statement. After the
parties have made their statements, they will be given the opportunity to pose
questions to the other party or make comments on the other party's statement. The Panel may pose any questions or make any
comments during such session. The
parties will also have an opportunity to make their closing statement during
the session open to the public.
3. To the extent that the Panel or any party
considers it necessary, the Panel will also hold a session with the parties not
open to public observation during which the parties will be allowed to make
additional statements or comments, and pose questions, that involve business
confidential information. The Panel may
also pose questions during such a session.
4. In addition to its sessions with the
parties, at the substantive meeting the Panel will also hold a separate session
with the third parties. The Panel will
start the third party session by opening a portion of this session to the
public. At this portion of the third
party session, any third party wishing to make its oral statement in a public
session shall do so. Following the third
party open session, the Panel will proceed to a third party closed session
during which any other third party shall make its oral statement. At each of these third party open or closed
sessions, after the third parties' statements, the Panel or any party may pose
questions to any third party or make comments concerning these statements.
Third parties may also ask questions to the parties or other third parties at
the invitation of the Panel; however, the parties and the other third parties
have no obligation to respond to these questions by third parties.
5. The following persons will be admitted into
the meeting room during all sessions of the Panel's substantive meeting,
whether open or closed to the public:
– the members of the Panel;
– all members of the delegations of the
parties to DS386 and DS384;
– all members of the delegations of the third
parties to DS384 and DS386; and
– WTO Secretariat staff assisting the Panel.
6. No person shall disclose any business
confidential information at any session open to the public.
7. WTO Members and Observers and the public
may observe the Panel's sessions that are open to the public by means of a real
time closed-circuit television broadcast to a separate viewing room. The broadcasts will be open to officials of
WTO Members and Observers upon presentation of their official badges. Accredited journalists and representatives of
relevant non-governmental organizations may indicate to the Secretariat their
interest in attending the broadcasts (Information and External Relations
Division). Members of the general public
will be invited to register their interest in attending each broadcast via the WTO
website, by close of business on 7 February 2014.
ANNEX
A-5
Procedures
of the Panel Concerning Business Confidential Information[3] (DS384)
Adopted on
28 October 2013
1. These procedures apply to any business
confidential information (BCI) that a party submits to the Panel.
2. For the purposes of these procedures, BCI
is defined as any information that has been designated as such by the Party
submitting the information, that is not available in the public domain and the
release of which could reasonably be considered to cause or threaten to cause
harm to an interest of the person or entity that supplied the business
information to the Party.
3. No person may have access to BCI except a member of the Secretariat or
the Panel, a party's or third party's employee participating in the dispute,
and a party's or third party's outside advisor for purposes of this dispute. However,
an outside advisor is not permitted access to BCI if that advisor is an officer
or employee of an enterprise engaged in the production, export, or import of
cattle, swine, beef, or pork. When a party or third party provides BCI to an
outside advisor who is an employee or officer of an industry association of
such enterprises, that party or third party shall obtain written assurances from
such advisor that he or she has read and understands these Working Procedures
and will not disclose any BCI in contravention of the Working Procedures.
4. A party or third party obtaining access to
BCI as a result of the BCI being submitted in this dispute shall treat it as
confidential, i.e. shall not disclose that information other than to those
persons authorized to receive it pursuant to these procedures. Each party and
third party shall have responsibility in this regard for its employees as well as
any outside advisors for the purposes of this dispute. BCI obtained under these
procedures may be used only for the purpose of providing information and
argumentation in this dispute.
5. A party or third party submitting or
referring to BCI in a document shall mark the cover and each page of the
document to indicate the presence of BCI in the document as follows: BCI shall be placed between double
brackets (for example, [[xx,xxx.xx]]). The cover and the top of each page of
the document shall contain the notice "Contains Business Confidential
Information". Any BCI
that is submitted in electronic form shall be clearly marked with the phrase
"Contains BCI" on a label on the storage medium, and clearly marked
with the phrase "Contains BCI" in the electronic file name.
6. In the case of an oral statement containing
BCI to be delivered in the session not open to public observation as foreseen
in paragraph 2 of the "Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the
Panel," the Panel should ensure that only persons authorized to have
access to BCI pursuant to these procedures are permitted to hear the statement.
7. The parties, third parties, and the Panel
shall store all documents containing BCI so as to prevent unauthorized access
to such information.
8. The Panel shall not disclose BCI, in its
report or in any other way, to persons not authorized under these procedures to
have access to BCI. The Panel may, however, make statements of conclusion drawn
from such information. Before the Panel makes its final report publicly
available, the Panel shall give each party an opportunity to ensure that the
report does not contain any information that it has designated as BCI.
9. Submissions containing BCI will be included
in the record forwarded to the Appellate Body in the event of an appeal of the
Panel's Report.
ANNEX A-6
Procedures
of the Panel Concerning Business Confidential Information[4] (DS386)
Adopted on
28 October 2013
1. These procedures apply to any business
confidential information (BCI) that a party submits to the Panel.
2. For the purposes of these procedures, BCI
is defined as any information that has been designated as such by the Party
submitting the information, that is not available in the public domain and the
release of which could reasonably be considered to cause or threaten to cause
harm to an interest of the person or entity that supplied the business
information to the Party.
3. No person may have access to BCI except a member of the Secretariat or
the Panel, a party's or third party's employee participating in the dispute,
and a party's or third party's outside advisor for purposes of this dispute. However,
an outside advisor is not permitted access to BCI if that advisor is an officer
or employee of an enterprise engaged in the production, export, or import of
cattle, swine, beef, or pork. When a party or third party provides BCI to an
outside advisor who is an employee or officer of an industry association of
such enterprises, that party or third party shall obtain written assurances
from such advisor that he or she has read and understands these Working
Procedures and will not disclose any BCI in contravention of the Working
Procedures.
4. A party or third party obtaining access to
BCI as a result of the BCI being submitted in this dispute shall treat it as
confidential, i.e. shall not disclose that information other than to those
persons authorized to receive it pursuant to these procedures. Each party and
third party shall have responsibility in this regard for its employees as well
as any outside advisors for the purposes of this dispute. BCI obtained under
these procedures may be used only for the purpose of providing information and
argumentation in this dispute.
5. A party or third party submitting or
referring to BCI in a document shall mark the cover and each page of the
document to indicate the presence of BCI in the document as follows: BCI shall be placed between double
brackets (for example, [[xx,xxx.xx]]). The cover and the top of each page of
the document shall contain the notice "Contains Business Confidential
Information". Any BCI
that is submitted in electronic form shall be clearly marked with the phrase
"Contains BCI" on a label on the storage medium, and clearly marked
with the phrase "Contains BCI" in the electronic file name.
6. In the case of an oral statement containing
BCI to be delivered in the session not open to public observation as foreseen
in paragraph 2 of the "Procedures for an open substantive meeting of the
Panel," the Panel should ensure that only persons authorized to have
access to BCI pursuant to these procedures are permitted to hear the statement.
7. The parties, third parties, and the Panel
shall store all documents containing BCI so as to prevent unauthorized access
to such information.
8. The Panel shall not disclose BCI, in its
report or in any other way, to persons not authorized under these procedures to
have access to BCI. The Panel may, however, make statements of conclusion drawn
from such information. Before the Panel makes its final report publicly
available, the Panel shall give each party an opportunity to ensure that the
report does not contain any information that it has designated as BCI.
9. Submissions containing BCI will be included
in the record forwarded to the Appellate Body in the event of an appeal of the
Panel's Report.
ANNEX B
Arguments
of the Parties
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex B-1
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Canada
|
B-2
|
Annex B-2
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Mexico
|
B-14
|
Annex B-3
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the United States
|
B-27
|
ANNEX B-1
integrated
executive summary of the argument of canada
I. introduction
1. In
a report issued on 29 June 2012, the Appellate Body confirmed that the COOL
measure of the United States accorded less favourable treatment to
imported livestock as compared to domestic livestock, in violation of the United States'
obligations under TBT Article 2.1. In response to this ruling, instead of
eliminating the incentive created by the COOL measure for U.S. market actors to
handle exclusively domestic livestock, the United States amended the
labelling requirements in a manner that further undermined the competitive
position of Canadian cattle and hogs in the U.S. market.
II. factual background
A. The
original COOL measure
2. The
original COOL measure provided that retailers licensed under the Perishable Agricultural Commodities Act, 1930 were required to provide consumers with origin
information on pork and beef muscle cuts that was loosely based on the location
of three production steps undergone by livestock: birth, raising, and slaughter.
Muscle cuts of pork and beef were divided into the following four categories:
Category
A
|
Meat from
animals born, raised, and slaughtered in the United States, or from animals
present in the United States on or prior to 15 July 2008
|
Product
of the U.S.
|
Category
B
|
Meat from
animals born in Country X and raised and slaughtered in the United States.
(These animals were not exclusively born, raised and slaughtered in the United States
or imported for immediate slaughter.)
|
Product
of the U.S., Country X, Country Y (if applicable; can appear in any
order)
|
Category
C
|
Meat from
animals imported into the United States for immediate slaughter
|
Product
of Country X, U.S.
|
Category
D
|
Foreign meat
imported into the United States
|
Product
of Country X
|
3. The
original COOL measure permitted the commingling of muscle cuts derived from
categories A, B, and C on a single production day. Where commingling occurred,
the muscle cuts could be labelled under a common, mixed-origin label (e.g.
"Product of Canada, United States"). Imported muscle cuts were
labeled so as to indicate that they were a product of the country in which the
animal from which they were produced was slaughtered (e.g. "Product of
Canada"), regardless of where the birth and raising steps occurred.
4. In
addition, the original COOL measure permitted labels that applied to ground
beef and pork to list countries if "raw material" from those
countries was in a processor's inventory less than 60 days prior to the ground
meat's production. This "60-day inventory allowance" flexibility was
available for market participants at every stage of meat supply and
distribution.
5. Large
amounts of pork and beef consumed in the United States were exempted from
the scope of the original COOL measure's application. Specifically, food
service establishments, all processed pork and beef, and retailers that either
purchased less than $230,000 worth of fresh fruits and vegetables annually or
that did not ship, receive, or contract to be shipped or received fresh fruits
and vegetables in quantities exceeding 2,000 pounds (one ton) in a single day
were exempt from the original COOL measure's labelling requirements.
B. The amended COOL measure
6. The
amendments to the original COOL measure introduced two major changes: (1) the
commingling flexibility, which had somewhat mitigated the original COOL
measure's segregation requirements, was eliminated; and (2) subject to certain
exceptions, labels applying to muscle cuts of beef and pork were required to
name the country (countries) in which the animal from which the muscle cut was
derived was born, was raised, and was slaughtered.
7. The amended COOL measure provides that if
an animal was raised in part in the United States and in part outside the United States,
the label may treat the animal as if it was raised entirely in the United States,
unless the animal was imported for immediate slaughter (when it is consigned
directly from a port of entry to a recognized slaughtering establishment and
slaughtered within two weeks from its date of entry) or where by doing so the
muscle cut covered commodity would be designated as having a United States
country of origin.
8. The
amended COOL measure did not modify the original COOL measure's extensive
exclusions and exemptions, the labelling of imported muscle cuts, or the 60‑day
inventory allowance that applies to ground beef and pork.
III. The scope of canada's challenge
9. Canada's
challenge of the amended COOL measure concerns the labelling of muscle cuts of
beef and pork derived from livestock slaughtered in the United States. Canada
does not make claims of inconsistency of the provisions of the amended COOL
measure pertaining to the labelling of muscle cuts of foreign origin imported
into the United States or the labelling of ground meat with the WTO
obligations of the United States. However, Canada refers to these
provisions of the amended COOL measure to demonstrate the WTO-inconsistency of
the labelling requirements in respect of muscle cuts of beef and pork derived
from livestock slaughtered in the United States.
IV. Legal claims
A. The amended COOL measure is a technical
regulation and Canadian cattle and hogs are "like"
U.S. Cattle and hogs
10. The
Panel concluded that the original COOL measure was a technical regulation. The United States
did not appeal this finding and this aspect did not become an issue in the
current compliance proceedings. The amended COOL measure equally qualifies as a
technical regulation. In the original proceedings, the
Panel concluded that Canadian cattle and hogs are "like" U.S. cattle
and hogs. This was not appealed in the previous proceedings and this aspect did
not become an issue in the current compliance proceedings either.
B. The amended COOL
measure violates TBT Article 2.1
1. The amended COOL measure accords less
favourable treatment to Canadian cattle and hogs, in violation of TBT Article 2.1
11. TBT Article 2.1 imposes a
national treatment obligation on WTO Members with respect to technical
regulations. The analysis of whether a technical regulation is de facto inconsistent
with TBT Article 2.1 consists of the following two inquiries:
(i) whether the technical regulation at issue modifies the conditions of
competition in the relevant market to the detriment of imported products
compared to like domestic products; and, if so, (ii) whether the detrimental
impact on imported products stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory
distinction (LRD).
12. The assessment under element (i) is the same test as that which applies
under GATT Article III:4 for determining whether a measure accords less
favourable treatment to imported products. The legal test under element (ii)
assesses both whether the regulatory distinction and technical regulation in
issue are designed and applied in an even-handed manner. In assessing
even-handedness, a panel must carefully scrutinize the particular circumstances
of the case, that is, the design, architecture, revealing structure, operation
and application of the technical regulation at issue.
13. As
a result of the removal of the commingling flexibility and the introduction of
point-of-production labelling through the 2013 Final Rule, the amended COOL
measure's labelling, recordkeeping, and segregation requirements are more
onerous than those that prevailed under the original COOL measure.
14. Throughout
the original proceedings, the United States argued that the original COOL
measure did not require the segregation of animals on the basis of their origin
because of the availability of commingling, which was alleged by the United States
to be widely used by producers. The elimination of the commingling flexibility
removes any pretence that segregation is not necessary under the COOL regime. This
view is confirmed by comments on the amended COOL measure that were submitted
by industry actors to the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) and referred to
by Canada in these proceedings.
15. Basic
economic logic suggests that the elimination of commingling and the resulting
additional recordkeeping and segregation requirements will further deter market
actors from handling Canadian livestock and the muscle cuts derived therefrom. The
United States resorts to both bald assertions regarding what it now
considers to have been the limited extent to which commingling occurred and
criticism directed at industry actors for failing to provide evidence regarding
the extent of commingling in practice.
16. The
United States further contends that Canada's claim regarding the amended
COOL measure's detrimental impact is based on the elimination of commingling. This
contention is without merit. While the prohibition of commingling has
exacerbated the original COOL measure's significant and negative impact, this
is by no means the sole basis for Canada's argument regarding the amended COOL
measure's detrimental impact. The amended COOL measure does nothing to alter
the elements of the original COOL measure that were responsible for undermining
the competitive position of Canadian cattle and hogs in the U.S. market.
17. The
amended COOL measure has increased the recordkeeping and verification
requirements that cause the segregation that is the source of the detrimental
impact on Canadian cattle and hogs.
18. As
a result of the commingling flexibility that applied under the original COOL
measure, producers could affix a common label to muscle cuts derived from
combinations of commingled Category A, B, and C animals. Both the provisions on
commingling that were set out in the 2009 Final Rule and the USDA's commentary
on that Rule reveal that the original COOL measure provided flexibility for
upstream producers that reduced the records that had to be kept in the case of
commingled muscle cuts. This flexibility has been eliminated by the amended
COOL measure.
19. Furthermore,
the original COOL measure permitted Category B muscle cuts to bear Label C,
even where no commingling occurred. In practical terms, only one set of records
was necessary to track Category B and C animals and the muscle cuts derived
therefrom. The elimination of this flexibility means that two sets of records
will now be required.
20. Canada has submitted evidence
that demonstrates the widespread expectation among a wide range of industry
actors, that recordkeeping will increase under the amended COOL measure, and
has provided practical examples that demonstrate the reasons for this
expectation.
21. The
United States acknowledges that compliance costs will rise as a result of
the changes introduced through the amended COOL measure but fails to recognize
that it is the structure of the North American markets for beef and pork muscle
cuts that ensures that Canadian cattle and hogs will bear a disproportionate
burden of those compliance costs.
22. The
U.S. market for cattle and hogs is dominated by U.S. animals. As a result, U.S.
market actors can usually avoid the segregation requirements of the amended
COOL measure by handling exclusively U.S. animals and muscle cuts derived
therefrom. In order to compete with these entities, market actors selling
muscle cuts or animals that have undergone a production step in Canada must
pass the higher costs of segregating and tracking Canadian cattle and hogs and
the muscle cuts derived therefrom up the supply chain to Canadian cattle and
hog producers. The amended COOL measure not only perpetuates this situation but
adds to the higher costs arising from the use of imported livestock, thereby
strengthening the incentive for U.S. producers to handle exclusively domestic
livestock.
23. Canada
has submitted extensive evidence demonstrating the detrimental impact that the
amended COOL measure has had on Canadian cattle and hogs, even with the
six-month delay in the amended COOL measure's enforcement. This evidence is
consistent both with basic economic logic, which is elaborated upon by Dr.
Sumner in his report on the amended COOL measure's economic impact on Canadian
livestock, and the expectations of industry actors that are documented by
Canada.
24. Canada
has shown that the amended COOL measure does not stem exclusively from a LRD,
in that the measure is arbitrary, lacks even‑handedness, and results in
unjustifiable discrimination against Canadian livestock.
25. The
United States attempts to limit the scope of the Panel's analysis under TBT
Article 2.1, adopting the position that the distinctions between the
categories of meat and the different labels should be considered in the
abstract, divorced from the amended COOL measure's overall architecture and
application. In so doing, the United States advocates an approach that
runs directly counter to both the analytical framework that the Appellate Body
has developed and applied under the LRD component of the TBT Article 2.1
test and to the analysis conducted by the Appellate Body in this case.
26. At
the core of the Appellate Body's approach are assessments of the even‑handedness
of both the challenged technical regulation and the relevant regulatory
distinction(s). These assessments require close scrutiny of the particular
circumstances of the case, that is, the design, architecture, revealing
structure, operation, and application of the technical regulation at issue.
27. An
important panel finding supporting the Appellate Body's conclusion that the
detrimental impact on Canadian cattle and hogs caused by the COOL measure did
not stem from a LRD was the "considerable proportion" of beef and
pork that is exempt from labelling requirements. The amended COOL measure does
not address the scope of the extensive exemptions to the original COOL measure
in any way.
28. Canada
has demonstrated that approximately 33% of beef and 9% of pork that is consumed
in the United States is subject to the amended COOL measure's labelling
requirements. These figures are broadly consistent with the findings of the
U.S. Congressional Research Service in its report on COOL and this WTO dispute.
Furthermore, factoring ground beef into this consideration shows that
approximately only 16% of all beef that is consumed in the U.S. bears labels
that provide origin information regarding the place of birth, raising, and
slaughter.
29. Thus,
despite the fact that information regarding the origin of all livestock must be
identified, tracked, and transmitted throughout the chain of production by
producers, processors, and retailers, the amended COOL measure conveys
information regarding the location of the three production steps on only a
fraction of the meat that is derived from this livestock. This reveals that a
lack of correspondence between the recordkeeping and verification requirements,
on the one hand, and the limited information provided to consumers, on the
other hand, persists under the amended COOL measure. Consequently, the
detrimental impact on Canadian cattle and hogs cannot be explained by the need
to provide origin information to consumers and, therefore, reflects arbitrary
and unjustifiable discrimination.
30. The
amended COOL measure purports to address the lack of correspondence between the
recordkeeping and verification requirements and the limited information conveyed
to consumers. However, the requirements of the latter half of this ratio have
been expanded by the amended COOL measure. Moreover, the increased
recordkeeping and verification requirements apply throughout the entire beef
and pork muscle cut supply chains, while the information conveyed through the
new labels is limited to the much smaller segment of beef and pork that is subject
to point‑of-production labelling. This more than offsets the contribution that
any additional information provided to consumers under the amended COOL measure
makes to the rectification of the imbalance described above.
31. The
Appellate Body considered that Label A was capable of conveying to
consumers that the livestock used to produce muscle cuts were born, raised, and
slaughtered in the United States. Label D remains unchanged under the
amended COOL measure. Therefore, any additional meaningful information provided
to consumers by the amended COOL measure is limited to those muscle cuts to
which Labels B and C were previously applied.
32. Even
if the United States' assertion that roughly 27 to 28% of pork and beef
muscle cuts that were subject to the original COOL measure bore Label B or
C is accepted, this means that the additional information provided to U.S.
consumers by the amended COOL measure applies to less than a third of all
muscle cuts that are subject to the amended COOL measure's labelling
requirements.
33. The
information conveyed to consumers by the amended COOL measure may be incomplete
or misleading, particularly with respect to the labels that apply to muscle
cuts that are derived from animals that do not satisfy the definition of U.S.
origin. For example: (1) Imported muscle cuts may be labeled as "Product
of Canada" even if the animal used to produce the muscle cut was born and
raised in the United States; (2) Muscle cuts may be labelled as
"Born in Canada, Raised and Slaughtered in the United States"
even if the animal from which the muscle cut is derived spends as little as 15
days in the United States prior to slaughter; (3) Labels affixed to an
animal that spends a short time in Canada prior to being exported to the United States
for immediate slaughter must be labelled as "Born and Raised in Canada,
Slaughtered in the United States".
34. The
United States describes the objective of the amended COOL measure as the
provision of accurate origin information to consumers. Yet, consideration of
the amended COOL measure's design, architecture, and revealing structure
demonstrates that significant dissonance exists between this objective and the
measure's operation and application. The following aspects of the amended COOL
measure's treatment of meat consumed in the United States illustrate this
point: (1) The only information on the location of the production steps that
can be relied on by U.S. consumers as accurate is that which is conveyed in
respect of muscle cuts that are derived from animals that satisfy the measure's
definition of U.S. origin; (2) As a result of the 60-day inventory allowance
that applies to ground beef and pork, consumers are only informed of the
countries of origin "that may be reasonably contained therein". The
USDA simply asserts that this is reasonable because precise labelling for
ground meat would be burdensome for industry, ignoring the contradiction with
its approach to muscle cut labels, which is also burdensome for industry; (3)
The amended COOL measure permits the omission of information on the raising
production step occurring in a foreign country if an animal is raised in both
the United States and a foreign country. However, this flexibility is
unavailable if an animal is born and raised in the United States, raised
in another country, and then raised and slaughtered in the United States. The
United States offers no explanation that accounts for this clear
contradiction that prioritizes U.S. origin information; (4) The amended
COOL measure continues to exempt food service establishments, processed foods,
and retailers that either do not purchase $230,000 worth of fresh fruit and
vegetables annually or do not ship, receive, or contract to be shipped or
received quantities of fresh fruit and vegetables in quantities exceeding 2,000
pounds (one ton) in a single day. This means that butcher shops, i.e. shops that specialize in selling meat products do not
provide consumers with origin information.
35. These
elements of the amended COOL measure reveal the uneven manner of its operation
and application to meat products and the animals from which they are produced. This
uneven application in turn demonstrates that the amended COOL measure and its
regulatory distinctions are arbitrary, and that the discrimination against
Canadian cattle is unjustifiable.
36. The
Panel's findings in respect of Label D were a factor in the Appellate
Body's analysis of the legitimacy of the original COOL measure's regulatory
distinctions. Furthermore, Label D is part of the amended COOL measure's
design, architecture, and revealing structure that affects its operation and
application. Therefore, Label D must factor into the Panel's LRD analysis.
37. Canada
is not challenging the consistency of the ground meat label with the WTO
obligations of the United States. However, the logic that underpinned the
Appellate Body's analysis weighs in favour of the amended COOL measure's
treatment of ground meat being regarded as a relevant factor in assessing the
measure's consistency with TBT Article 2.1.
38. Cattle
and hogs, which are used to produce both muscle cuts and ground meat, are
subject to the amended COOL measure's onerous tracking and verification
requirements, despite the fact that a large portion of the meat derived from
these animals (i.e. ground meat) does not convey the information that must be
tracked and transmitted upstream. This element of the amended COOL measure
supports the following conclusions: (i) the detrimental impact on Canadian
cattle and hogs that results from the recordkeeping and verification
requirements cannot be explained by the need to provide origin information on
the location of the three production steps; and (ii) the amended COOL measure,
therefore, reflects discrimination.
39. The
prohibition of trace-back is a relevant consideration in assessing whether the
amended COOL measure's detrimental impact on Canadian livestock reflects
discrimination. This prohibition, coupled with a mandate for the Secretary of
Agriculture to audit retailers to verify compliance, necessitates the
implementation of the amended COOL measure's labelling requirements through the
system of recordkeeping and verification that is the cause of the detrimental
impact on Canadian livestock. Therefore, the prohibition on trace-back is a
critical element in demonstrating that the detrimental impact on Canadian
livestock does not stem exclusively from a LRD.
C. The amended COOL
measure violates GATT Article III:4
40. The Appellate body has clarified that the national treatment
obligations in TBT Article 2.1 and GATT Article III:4 differ in scope
and content. As a result, Canada requests that, regardless of the Panel's
findings under TBT Article 2.1, the Panel address Canada's claim under
GATT III:4.
41. According "treatment no less favourable" in the context
of a de facto violation of GATT Article III:4
means according conditions of competition no less favourable to the imported
product than to the like domestic product. The analysis of a measure's effect
on the conditions of competition in the context of TBT Article 2.1 applies
equally to GATT Article III:4.
42. Notwithstanding the long line of jurisprudence that has applied
the GATT Article III:4 analysis, the United States seeks to import
the LRD component of the TBT Article 2.1 test into this analysis. There is
no textual basis for the position of the United States, which disregards
the specific context in which the LRD analysis was developed and the context
provided for in the GATT 1994 itself.
43. The genesis of the LRD analysis is the balance between the right
to regulate and the commitment to liberalize trade that is provided for in the
context of the TBT Agreement and also reflected in GATT Articles III
and XX. That balance is reflected in both GATT Articles III and XX (as well as in the
two-step TBT Article 2.1 test) accounts for the Appellate
Body's clarification that the scope and context of TBT Article 2.1 and
GATT Article III:4 are not the same.
44. The United States fails to explain how an assessment of
whether a challenged technical regulation is applied in a manner that would
constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination, as is required
in the LRD analysis under the TBT Agreement would somehow apply under GATT 1994.
In particular, the United States does not explain how the assessment of
arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination that it proposes to read into GATT Article III:4
would interact with the assessment under the chapeau of GATT Article XX of
whether the challenged measure is "applied in a manner that would
constitute arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where
the same conditions prevail".
45. The extensive jurisprudence interpreting the relationship between
GATT Article III and XX should not be jettisoned through the importation
of the interpretation of TBT Article 2.1 into the GATT. Accepting the United States' position on this point would defy
basic principles of treaty interpretation and create uncertainty among Members
about the scope of both the WTO commitments that they have agreed to and that
are under negotiation.
46. If the United States had
legitimate regulatory purposes relevant for an analysis under the GATT 1994,
it should have put forward a GATT Article XX defence. Having failed to do
so, it cannot now seek to twist the GATT Article III:4 test to pretend
that it does not need Article XX of GATT 1994.
D. The amended COOL measure violates TBT Article 2.2
47. Two issues are in dispute: (i) the
identification of the objective, and; (ii) the necessity of the
trade-restrictiveness of the amended COOL measure.
48. The objective of a measure is the
benchmark on a scale against which to assess the actual contribution of the
measure to the fulfilment of the objective. If defined too narrowly, an
objective may more easily correlate with the measure that is being challenged
and, as a result, affect the comparison with alternative measures by reducing
the possibility of formulating measures that achieve a level of fulfilment of
the objective that is equivalent to that achieved by the challenged measure.
49. In the original proceedings, the
Appellate Body confirmed the Panel's finding that the United States'
objective was "the provision of consumer information on origin". The United States
nevertheless contends that its objective may be stated in a number of ways,
including more narrowly as "to provide consumers with information on the
countries in which the livestock from which the meat they purchase is produced
were born, raised and slaughtered". The Panel should reject the United States'
attempt to reformulate its objective in an artificially narrow and self-serving
manner, all the more because the United States has conceded that its
objective remains the provision of consumer information on origin.
50. Assessing the necessity of the
trade-restrictiveness of a measure involves the consideration of the following
factors: (i) the trade-restrictiveness
of the regulation; (ii) the degree of contribution the regulation makes to
the achievement of the objective, and (iii) the nature of the risks are issue
and the gravity of the consequences that would arise from non-fulfilment of the
objective pursued through the measure. In most cases, the analysis involves a
comparison with alternative measures.
51. A measure is trade-restrictive if it has a limiting effect on
trade. A measure that affects the conditions of competition to the detriment of
imported products is trade‑restrictive. An actual reduction in trade flows is
not a conditio sine qua non for a measure to
be considered trade-restrictive. A technical
regulation that increases compliance costs in a non‑discriminatory manner, but
does not otherwise modify the conditions of competition to the detriment of
imported products, may nevertheless be trade-restrictive if the cost increase
has the effect of reducing trade flows or reducing prices of both imported and
domestic products. The amended COOL measure is highly trade-restrictive.
52. WTO jurisprudence recognizes that
panels enjoy a certain latitude in choosing and designing the methodology to
assess the contribution of a measure to the fulfilment of the measure's
objective. There is no reason why panels should not enjoy the same latitude in
choosing the methodology to assess the trade-restrictiveness of a measure. Contrary
to the position expressed by the United States, trade-restrictiveness is
not exclusively concerned with trade volumes. The assessment of
trade-restrictiveness is concerned with the impact of a
measure on imports. Such an impact may be, inter alia, a
reduction in prices or quantities or both, as in this case.
53. The assessment of the contribution
is concerned with the degree of contribution that the technical regulation actually makes towards the achievement of the objective. There
is no requirement for a panel to identify, in the abstract, the level at which
a responding Member aims to achieve that objective. The Appellate Body has
explained that a Member, "by preparing, adopting, and applying a measure
in order to pursue a legitimate objective, articulates either implicitly or
explicitly the level at which it seeks to pursue that particular legitimate
objective".
54. Contrary to the contention of the United States, whether an
alternative measure provides an equivalent "amount" of information on
the countries where the animal was born, raised and slaughtered is not the
"only question". Further, determining the actual degree of
contribution of a measure does not preclude characterizing that degree as, for
instance, "low" or "limited". Such characterization allows
comparing the degree of contribution of the challenged measure with alternative
measures that contribute to the objective in a different way.
55. The amended COOL measure is capable of contributing towards its
objective to a very limited degree. A considerable proportion of beef and pork
sold in the United States continues to be exempted from the labelling
requirements.
56. The obligation to consider the "risks non-fulfilment would
create" means that the comparison of the challenged measure with a
possible alternative measure should be made in the light of the nature of the
risks at issue and the gravity of the consequences that would arise from
non-fulfilment of the legitimate objective. In
this case, the consequence that would arise from non-fulfilment would be that
those consumers who want information on the origin of source livestock might
not be able to get it. The Appellate Body has already found that the consequences
that may arise from non‑fulfilment of the objective would not be particularly
grave.
57. The comparison with possible
alternative measures is a conceptual tool
for ascertaining whether the challenged measure is more trade-restrictive than
necessary. As with any analytical tool, it must not be applied in a mechanistic
fashion. It is relevant to determine whether the alternative is less
trade-restrictive, whether it would make an equivalent contribution to the
relevant objective, taking into account the risks non-fulfilment would create,
and whether it is reasonably available. An alternative measure is not
reasonably available if it imposes an undue burden on the responding Member,
such as prohibitive costs or substantial technical difficulties. The reasonable
availability of an alternative measure must be assessed in relation to the capacity of the responding Member to
implement it.
58. A comparison with an alternative
measure that is less trade-restrictive than the challenged measure but fulfils the
responding Party's objective to a lesser extent does not preclude a finding
that the challenged measure is more trade-restrictive than necessary. Such a
finding would require that the consequences that would arise from
non-fulfilment of the objective would not be grave.
59. Turning to the comparative
analysis, Canada submitted a detailed analysis prepared by Dr. Sumner to assist the Panel in making a determination on the
trade-restrictiveness element (Exhibit CDA-126). That
analysis calculates the magnitude of compliance costs required for a non-discriminatory
alternative measure to cause an impact on trade equal to the impact of the
original COOL measure. The impact is calculated in terms of export revenue losses in dollar amounts. The concept of export
revenue losses captures the meaning of trade restrictiveness because it is a measurement of the magnitude of the
impact of a measure on imports. Dr. Sumner used the
costs of the original COOL measure to Canadian producers – in the sense of the
losses that the measure has caused them, both in terms of reduced prices and
quantities – to calculate how much tracing livestock and meat, labelling meat
and keeping records would need to cost to market participants under a
non-discriminatory measure to cause Canadian producers the same export losses
as under the original COOL measure. In Exhibit CDA‑126, Dr. Sumner has
demonstrated that a non‑discriminatory alternative measure would have to entail
implausibly high compliance costs to cause such losses. These already
implausibly high minimum amounts of compliance costs are even much higher when
calculated based on the export revenue losses caused by the amended COOL
measure or on quantities alone, further to the United States' conception
of trade-restrictiveness. None of the alternative measures could possibly
entail compliance costs of the magnitude calculated.
60. The United States has not
rebutted Canada's prima facie case that any one of
the proposed alternative measures would be less trade-restrictive than the amended
COOL measure.
61. First alternative measure – Mandatory labelling of muscle cuts of
beef and pork based on substantial transformation could be implemented,
combined with voluntary labelling for the production steps of birth and raising.
This measure would be significantly less trade-restrictive than the amended
COOL measure because it would not require segregation of livestock and muscle
cuts for that segment of the market that does not voluntarily provide consumer
information on where livestock were born and raised. The United States has
not contested that this alternative measure is reasonably available.
62. While this alternative measure might not contribute to the
fulfilment of the objective to the exact same degree as the amended COOL
measure, that consideration does not preclude the Panel from finding that the
amended COOL measure is more trade‑restrictive than necessary. This is so
because the consequences that may arise from non-fulfilment of the objective of
the amended COOL measure are not particularly grave. Based on the following
factors, considered in conjunction, the Panel should find that the amended COOL
measure is more trade-restrictive than necessary: the amended COOL measure is
capable of contributing towards its objective to a very limited degree; the
amended COOL measure is highly trade-restrictive; any difference in the degrees
of fulfilment of the objective between the two measures is not considerable,
given that the alternative measure would have a broader scope of application than
the amended COOL measure, and; the alternative measure would be significantly
less trade restrictive than the amended COOL measure.
63. Second alternative measure – The 60-day inventory allowance
flexibility applicable to ground meat could be extended to muscle cuts of beef
and pork. This alternative measure would be significantly less
trade-restrictive than the amended COOL measure, because market participants
throughout the meat supply chain would have sufficient flexibility as a result
of less intense segregation requirements. Also, the alternative measure could not possibly entail costs of the magnitude calculated by
Dr. Sumner to track livestock and meat, label meat and keep records. This alternative measure is reasonably
available. While this alternative measure, like the first alternative measure,
might not contribute to the fulfilment of the objective to the exact same
degree as the amended COOL measure, that consideration does not preclude the
Panel from finding that the amended COOL measure is more trade-restrictive than
necessary for the same reasons Canada provided with respect to the first
alternative measure.
64. Third alternative measure – A mandatory trace-back system could be
implemented to provide information, with respect to covered muscle cuts derived
from livestock slaughtered in the United States, on where the production
steps took place for the relevant source animal or group of animals. Tellingly,
the amended COOL measure prohibits the
USDA from using a trace-back system.
65. The first stage of a trace-back system involves the establishment
of an animal identification and traceability system. Several WTO Members have
established such a system. The United States once had a comprehensive
voluntary system – the National Animal Identification System (NAIS) – that
could have been maintained and made mandatory to provide information to
consumers. The second stage of a trace-back system occurs at the
slaughterhouse, where processors have to preserve the link between the animal,
or group of animals, and the muscle cuts. Preserving
the link between the animal, or groups of animals, and the muscle cuts is done
on a country-wide and commercial basis in at least two WTO Members, namely
Japan and Uruguay; various supply chains elsewhere on the globe also preserve
that link. Most of the compliance costs under a trace-back system would be
incurred at that stage. The third stage of a trace-back system involves the
distributors and the retailers, who have to preserve the information about the
muscle cut.
66. A trace-back system would achieve a contribution to the fulfilment
of the objective that is equal to or greater than the contribution achieved by
the amended COOL measure. The label on a muscle
cut could indicate the precise name and address of the facility where each of
the production steps took place. However, as an alternative, the labelling
requirements under a trace-back system could be the same as those under the
amended COOL measure, provided that market participants be able to demonstrate,
if audited, that a muscle cut has been derived from an animal, or group of
animals, that was born, raised and slaughtered at a
specific location.
67. Also, a trace-back system would be less trade-restrictive than the
amended COOL measure. This is so because it could
be implemented in such a way as to avoid modifying the conditions of
competition to the detriment of imported livestock and it could not possibly
entail the minimum amounts of compliance costs calculated by Dr. Sumner.
68. Further, a trace-back system is a
reasonably available alternative measure. It would be unreasonable for the United States
to expect Canadian producers to continue shouldering the burden of a measure
that affects the competitive conditions of imported livestock when all market
participants could share equally the burden of providing consumer information
on origin. Further, there is no evidence that the first stage of a trace-back
system would reward vertical integration at the expense of family farms in the United States.
While a trace-back system would likely increase compliance costs for U.S.
producers (and would lower the overall enormous costs borne by Canadian
producers), these costs would not be prohibitive; the U.S. industry would
remain profitable. The experience of other countries' industries demonstrates
that changes in production practices are well within the capacity of the U.S.
industry. Finally, given that the United States has asserted that
providing consumer information on origin is very important, the United States
should be expected to use its capabilities to implement its objective
consistently with its WTO obligations.
69. Fourth alternative measure – In addition to the existing
requirements of the amended COOL measure to designate the country or countries
where production steps occurred on labels of muscle cuts of beef and pork
derived from livestock slaughtered in the United States, the designation
of the state(s) and/or province(s) where each of those steps occurred could
also be required on those labels.
70. The proposed alternative measure would achieve a greater degree of
fulfilment than that achieved by the amended COOL measure, because it would
provide the same consumer information as that provided under the amended COOL
measure, with the addition of other information.
71. The proposed alternative would also be less trade-restrictive than
the amended COOL measure. This is so because it
could be implemented in such a way as to avoid modifying the conditions of
competition to the detriment of imported livestock and it could not possibly
entail the minimum amounts of compliance costs calculated by Dr. Sumner.
72. The proposed alternative measure is reasonably available. State/province
designations may already be used in lieu of country of origin labeling for, inter alia, perishable agricultural commodities. Also, the
alternative measure is based on the principle that animals should be traceable when in interstate commerce in the United States,
which is operationalized in the Final Rule on Traceability for
Livestock Moving Interstate (Final Rule on Traceability). The fourth alternative measure would entail lower compliance costs
than a trace-back system. Further, animals would not need to have been raised
in all the same states or provinces; it would be sufficient that they have the
last state/province in common. The United States could rely on the
segregation of animals on a state/province basis and on documents generated
pursuant to, or required under, the Final Rule on Traceability, combined with
requirements for producer's affidavits for elements that are not currently
fully covered under that Rule, to implement the fourth alternative measure. Alternatively,
the United States could implement a national animal identification and
traceability system, as many other WTO Members have done. The United States
once had such a system – i.e. the NAIS – but decided not to make it mandatory. Neither
solution proposed by Canada to implement the fourth alternative measure would
represent an undue burden for the United States.
E. The
COOL measure nullifies or impairs benefits that have accrued to Canada within
the meaning of GATT Article XXIII:1(b)
73. The amended COOL measure also
nullifies or impairs benefits that have accrued to Canada on the basis of
tariff concessions made by the United States in respect of live cattle and
hogs as part of the Uruguay Round. These tariff concessions apply on a most‑favoured-nation
(MFN) basis.
74. The
three elements that, according to the WTO jurisprudence, must exist for a
finding of non-violation nullification or impairment in the sense of GATT Article XXIII:1(b),
are all present in this case: (1) The application of the amended COOL measure
by the United States has deprived Canada of benefits; (2) The benefits
that have accrued to Canada from which Canada has been deprived are tariff
concessions made by the United States in the Uruguay Round, on the basis
of which Canada is entitled to rely for its expectation that its live cattle
and hogs will have unimpeded access to the U.S. market; and (3) By applying the
requirements of the amended COOL measure, the United States has upset the
competitive relationship between U.S. and Canadian livestock, and has nullified
or impaired the benefits accruing to Canada under the GATT 1994.
75. The benefits concerned accrued to
Canada under the WTO Agreement, regardless of the operation of the Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement (Canada-United States
FTA) and of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), by virtue of which
Canadian live cattle and hogs are entitled to duty-free entry into the United States.
76. The current MFN rate of the United States
under the WTO Agreement for cattle other than for dairy or breeding is US $
0.01 per kilogram. The duty-free import of hogs into the United States
pre-dates the WTO Agreement (as well as the Canada-United States FTA and
the NAFTA). These tariff concessions would apply if in the future Canada or the
United States were to withdraw from the NAFTA or if the NAFTA were to be
suspended by agreement between Canada and the United States.
77. Canada provided detailed
justification for its claim under GATT Article XXIII:1(b), in paras.
182-190 of its first written submission and in paras. 154-157 of its second
written submission. In addition, Canada has placed on the record extensive
evidence on the upset by the COOL measure, both in its original and amended
form, of the conditions of competition between Canadian and US cattle and hogs.
Canada has established a prima facie case,
which the United States has failed to rebut.
78. Meat from Canadian cattle and hogs
imported into the United States and subsequently slaughtered there was
considered, until the adoption of the COOL measure, to be a U.S. product and
was allowed to be marketed as such in the United States. The upset of the
competitive relationship between Canadian livestock and U.S. livestock caused
by the original COOL measure and continued and
aggravated by the amended COOL measure could not reasonably have been
anticipated by Canada.
79. The United States tries to
confuse the issue by referring to its meat labelling legislation of the U.S. Tariff Act of 1930, which concerns only the labelling of
imported muscle cuts. Therefore, this Act is irrelevant in terms of Canada's
reasonable expectations as to the importation of Canadian cattle and hogs into
the United States and their competitive position in the U.S. market.
80. The issue of the origin labelling
of muscle cuts derived from imported animals that were subsequently slaughtered
in the United States did not arise before 2003, when a Proposed Rule was
published under the 2002 Farm Bill, well after the conclusion of the Uruguay
Round and the entry into force of the WTO Agreement. It is the rejection of the
long-standing principle of substantial transformation in the COOL measure that
has upset the competitive position of Canadian cattle and hogs in the U.S.
market. There is no merit in the suggestion of the United States that
because of the U.S. Tariff Act of 1930
Canada could have foreseen the COOL measure and its effects on muscle cuts
derived from Canadian cattle and hogs slaughtered in the United States. Even
under the original and amended COOL measure the United States has
continued to apply substantial transformation in respect of imported muscle
cuts (Label D) and muscle cuts from animals slaughtered in the United States
destined for export from the United States.
81. As to the assertion of the United States
that the Panel lacks jurisdiction to deal with the claim of non-violation under
GATT Article XXIII:1(b), Canada refers to the words "consistency with
a covered agreement" in Article 21.5 of the Understanding on Rules
and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes (DSU). The terms
"consistency with a covered agreement" are broad enough to cover a
non-violation case because "consistency" can have a meaning that is
broader than a violation or infringement of a covered agreement.
82. Article 26.1 of the DSU sets
out a series of special rules that apply to non-violation claims under GATT Article XXIII:1(b).
The jurisdiction of a compliance panel to make findings of non-violations was
not ousted by DSU Article 26.1. To the contrary, the first sentence of DSU
Article 26.1 confirms the jurisdiction of "a panel" in general to make such a finding. This
applies equally to a panel acting under DSU Article 21.5. Furthermore,
from a systemic perspective, there is no good reason why a non-violation claim
could not be heard by the Panel, particularly in a case like this, in which a
similar claim was made in respect of the original COOL measure in the previous
phase of the litigation but no finding was made in respect of that claim.
83. Because the COOL measure was
adopted well after the conclusion of the Uruguay Round and the entry into force
of the WTO Agreement, Canada is entitled to benefit from the presumption
articulated by the panel in Japan-Film,
at para. 10.79 of its Report, i.e. that a measure that was adopted
following the conclusion of tariff negotiations could not have been foreseen by
the complaining Member and that it is up to the defending Member to rebut that
presumption. Canada has established a prima facie
case of non‑violation, which has not been rebutted by the United States.
V. request for relief
84. Canada requests the Panel to find that the amended COOL measure:
(i) continues the violation of Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
previously found in respect of the original COOL measure; (ii) violates Article III:4
of the GATT 1994; and (iii) violates Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
Canada also request the Panel to find that the amended COOL measure nullifies
or impairs benefits accruing to Canada under the GATT 1994, within the
meaning of Article XXIII:1(b) of that Agreement.
ANNEX B-2
INTEGRATED
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE ARGUMENTS OF MEXICO
I. INTRODUCTION and background information
1. This proceeding, under Article 21.5 of the DSU, concerns a
disagreement as to the consistency with the covered agreements of measures
taken to comply with the recommendations and rulings of the DSB in the dispute United States – Certain Country of Origin Labelling (COOL)
Requirements.
2. Mexico has initiated this proceeding to address the failure of the United States
to comply with its WTO obligations in relation to its mandatory "country
of origin" labeling system ("COOL") for
muscle cuts of beef. A measure that is found to be inconsistent with a core
non-discrimination provision cannot later be found by a compliance Panel to be
consistent with that obligation if the arbitrary and unjustifiable
discriminatory effects of the measure have not been removed, or, as in the
present case, have been increased.
3. This dispute was
initiated by Mexico in December 2008 and it has been ongoing for more than five
years without a positive resolution. It is now 2014, and Mexico's cattle
producers face even worse discrimination and trade restrictions than they did
in 2010. The Amended COOL Measure still has the effect of requiring all
imported cattle to be segregated. The measure continues to discourage the use
of imported cattle in meat production and there is still a "COOL discount"
imposed on Mexican cattle. There are still restrictions on the number of U.S.
processing plants that will accept Mexican cattle and on the days at which
Mexican cattle can be delivered.
4. The Panel and Appellate Body ("AB") Reports found that the
"COOL Measure", particularly in regard to the muscle cut meat labels,
is inconsistent with Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement because it
accords less favourable treatment to imported livestock than to like domestic livestock.
The DSB recommended that the United States bring the COOL Measure into
conformity with the United States' obligations under the covered
agreements.
5. The reasonable period of time was determined through binding
arbitration under Article 21.3(c) of the DSU, to be the 23 May 2013. On 12
March 2013, the United States published in the Federal Register a proposed
rule to amend the COOL regulations. On 23 May 2013 USDA published the "Final
Rule on Mandatory Country of Origin Labeling of Beef, Pork, Lamb, Chicken,
Goat Meat, Wild and Farm-Raised Fish and Shellfish, Perishable Agricultural
Commodities, Peanuts, Pecans, Ginseng, and Macadamia Nuts" (the "2013
Final Rule"), which made only minor changes to the proposed rule. The
Final Rule purportedly entered into force on that same date, although the
notice published with the rule indicates that the new regulation would not
actually be enforced for an additional six months. Although the COOL Statute
was part of the measure found by the Panel and the AB to be inconsistent with Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement, the United States did not modify the Statute.
In this sense, the United States has failed to bring the COOL Measure – as
a whole – into compliance.
6. The Amended COOL Measure has in fact strengthened the incentive to
favour domestic livestock in meat production by imposing higher segregation
costs and further adversely affecting competitive conditions in the U.S. market to the detriment
of imported livestock. The measure continues to discourage
the use of imported cattle in meat production and there is still a "COOL
discount" imposed on Mexican cattle.
II. THE AMENDED COOL MEASURE
7. The Amended COOL
Measure includes the COOL Statute and the 2009 Final Rule, as amended by the
2013 Final Rule. As stated
by the Panel and confirmed by the AB the statutory and regulatory provisions
were an integral part of one single COOL measure. The COOL Statute maintains a
close legal and substantive link with the 2013 Final Rule and remains an
integral part of the Amended COOL Measure.
8. The Amended COOL Measure entailed
changes only in the implementing regulations, and not in the COOL Statute. The
COOL Statute is contained in the Agricultural Marketing Act of 1946, as amended
by the Farm Bill 2002 and the Farm Bill 2008. These provisions were codified in
the United States Code ("U.S.C."), in Title 7 (Agriculture),
Chapter 38 (Distribution and Marketing of Agricultural Products), Subchapter IV
(Country of Origin Labeling) (hereinafter the "COOL Statute").
9. The COOL Statute excludes from the scope of the COOL requirements
covered commodities that are used as an ingredient in a processed food item,
those that are served or sold in "food service establishments" (e.g.,
restaurants, cafeterias, etc.). The law also does not apply to retailers who do
not sell fruits and/or vegetables (e.g., butcher shops) or to products destined
for export.
10. The 2009 Final Rule
repeated the requirements from the statute for origin labeling for covered beef
products. As described by the Panel, the options were as follows. For a product
to be eligible to be labelled as U.S. origin – the animals from which the meat
was derived must have been born, raised and slaughtered in the United States
(known as "Label A").
For products made from animals born in another country/ies, and raised and
slaughtered in the United States, the regulations authorized the use of a
label that would say "Product of the United States, Country X
and (as applicable) Country Y" (known as "Label B"). For products made
from animals born and raised in another country and imported for immediately
slaughter, the regulations required that the name of the foreign country be
listed first: "Product of Country X and the United States"
(known as "Label C").
11. The 2009 Final Rule added a feature to the rules that was not
addressed by the statute. Specifically, the commingling provisions allows that
muscle cuts processed on the same production day contained meat from animals
born in another country and animals born in the United States could be
labelled "Product of the United States, Country X, and (as
applicable) Country Y." The 2013 Final Rule eliminated these
flexibilities.
12. For ground beef, the label must list all countries of origin
contained therein or that may be reasonably contained therein. In determining
what is considered reasonable, when a raw material from a specific origin is
not in a processor's inventrory for more than 60 days, that country may no
longer be included as a possible country of origin. Mexico is not challenging
the application of the Amended COOL Measure to ground beef.
13. The Amended COOL Measure has not changed in relation to the scope of
coverage, the definitions of "origin," the labeling requirements for
imported meat products, the recordkeeping, verification and enforcement
provisions, or the labelling rules for ground meat. As with the original COOL
Measure, the Amended COOL Measure applies only
to: (i) meat in the form of muscle cuts and ground beef, and not to other
edible portions of the animal such as the liver, tongue and head; (ii) only to
covered products sold in major grocery stores, and not to such items sold in
food service establishments (e.g., restaurants and cafeterias) and smaller
retailers, including butcher shops; and does not apply to: (i) covered products
that are an ingredient in a processed food item; and (ii) to exported products,
which in the case of beef constitutes about 10 percent of total U.S.
production.
III. LEGAL ARGUMENT
14. The Amended COOL Measure is inconsistent with the obligations of the
United States under Articles 2.1 and 2.2 of the TBT Agreement,
and Article III:4 of the GATT 1994. It also nullifies or impairs
benefits that accrue to Mexico under the GATT 1994 within the meaning of Article XXIII:1(b).
Mexico requests that the Panel rule
on each of Mexico's claims and avoid exercising judicial economy. This is
necessary to achieve a satisfactory resolution of this dispute.
A. TERMS
OF REFERENCE OF THE PANEL
15. It is necessary for the Panel to rule on all of Mexico's claims under Articles 2.1
and 2.2 of the TBT Agreement and Article III:4 of the GATT 1994,
its obligations scope and content are not the same.
16. In US – Tuna II (Mexico), the AB clarified
the boundaries of judicial economy. It criticized the panel for exercising
false judicial economy by not ruling on Mexico's claims under Articles I
and III:4 of the GATT 1994 ("panels may
refrain from ruling on every claim as long as it does not lead to a "partial
resolution of the matter"). This finding is particularly relevant given
the differences of Articles 2.1 and 2.2 of the TBT Agreement and Article III:4
of the GATT 1994.
17. If the Panel does not make all findings under Mexico's other claims
and there is an appeal, the AB would be unable to complete the analysis of
those claims, and there would only be a partial resolution. Taking into account
that in the original proceedings the AB was unable to complete the legal
analysis under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement due to the absence of
relevant factual findings by the Panel and of sufficient undisputed facts on
the record, the Panel should make clear findings regarding all factors of the
Amended COOL Measure and proposed less trade-restrictive alternative measure.
18. The claims advanced by Mexico are raised exclusively in respect of the
measure "taken to comply" –"that is, in
principle, a new and different measure" –and do not, as the United States alleges,
constitute attempts to re-open the adopted findings of the DSB. Further to the
original proceedings, the DSB adopted the finding that the original COOL
Measure was inconsistent with Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement, but
as for Article 2.2 there were insufficient factual findings and undisputed
evidence on the record for the AB to complete the analysis.
19. Similarly, no findings were made in respect of Mexico's claims under
Articles III:4 and XXIII:1(b) of the GATT 1994 due to the exercise of
judicial economy. None of the
claims raised by Mexico against the Amended COOL Measure under Articles 2.1
and 2.2 of the TBT Agreement and Articles III:4 and XXIII:1(b) of the
GATT 1994 impinge on the finality of any findings, recommendations, or
rulings adopted by the DSB in relation to the original proceedings. Hence,
nothing precludes the Panel from considering these claims in respect of the
Amended COOL Measure in the present proceedings.
B. THE AMENDED COOL MEASURE
IS INCONSISTENT WITH ARTICLE 2.1 OF THE TBT AGREEMENT
20. For a violation of the national treatment obligation in Article 2.1
to be established, three elements must be satisfied: (i) the measure at issue
must be a "technical regulation"; (ii) the imported and domestic
products at issue must be like products; and (iii) the treatment accorded to
imported products must be less favourable than that accorded to like domestic
products.
1. Technical Regulation
21. In order
to qualify as a "technical regulation" within the meaning of the
definition in Annex 1.1, a document must: (i) apply to
an identifiable product or group of products; (ii) lay down one or more
characteristics of the product; and (iii) require mandatory compliance with the
product characteristics.
22. The Amended COOL Measure is a "technical regulation". The
AB acknowledged the Panel's finding that the original COOL Measure is a "technical
regulation" which is subject to the requirements of Article 2 of the TBT Agreement,
and observed that this finding was not challenged in the appeal. For the same
reasons as those on which the Panel's finding was based in respect of the COOL
Measure, the Amended COOL Measure continues to be a "technical regulation"
for the purposes of the TBT Agreement.
2. Like Products
23. The relevant imported and domestic products – in the case of Mexico's
cattle, in particular feeder cattle – also continue to be "like".
Although the labeling requirements at issue apply to muscle cuts of beef, by
its structure and design, the Amended COOL Measure applies indirectly to
cattle. The effect of that measure –indeed its core purpose– is to regulate the
inputs to muscle cuts –namely, cattle.
24. Before the Panel, the United States did not contest the
arguments presented by the complainants that the products at issue are "like"
and did not dispute the proposition that the only basis of distinction between
the products at issue is that of origin. The factual circumstances of the
relevant imported and domestic products have neither changed nor been affected
in any way by the adoption of the Amended COOL Measure. The same kinds of
Mexican cattle and the same kinds of U.S. cattle remain the products at issue. Hence,
the relevant imported and domestic products continue to be "like".
3. Treatment no Less Favourable
25. The AB has established a two-step approach for assessing whether a
technical regulation accords less favourable treatment under Article 2.1:
(i) whether the measure at issue modifies the conditions of competition in the
relevant market to the detriment of imported products as compared to like
domestic products or products originating in any other Member; and (ii) whether
any detrimental impact reflects discrimination against the imported products.
a. The
Amended COOL Measure Modifies Competitive Opportunities to the Detriment of
Imports
26. As explained by the AB in US – COOL, when
a panel
determines whether the operation of a measure, in the relevant market, has a de facto detrimental impact on the group of like
imported products, its analysis must take into consideration the totality of
the facts and circumstances before it, including any implications for competitive
conditions discernible from the design and structure of the measure itself, as
well as all features of the market at issue that are relevant to the measure's
operation within that market.
27. There have been no material changes made in the Amended COOL Measure
to the design and structure of the COOL Measure that were found by the Panel
and the AB to modify the competitive opportunities in the U.S. market to the
detriment of the imported products at issue. The key elements of the design and
structure of the measure that operated together to deny competitive
opportunities were: (i) the mandatory labelling requirement, (ii) the "born,
raised and slaughtered" requirement to determine origin, (iii) the
recordkeeping requirement and verification requirement, and (iv) the
enforcement requirement. These elements remain integral components of the
Amended COOL Measure.
28. Although the Panel and the AB highlighted the recordkeeping and
verification requirements of the COOL Measure, it was not these requirements,
in isolation, that modified the competitive opportunities. These requirements
operate in conjunction with other important elements of the measure explained below, that collectively deny
competitive opportunities. Accordingly, as was the case with the original COOL
Measure, it is the collective effect of the foregoing four elements of the
Amended COOL Measure that continues to deny competitive opportunities.
29. Because the features of the relevant market also remain unchanged,
the denial of competitive opportunities for Mexican cattle that the Panel and
the AB found to be caused by the COOL Measure has continued unabated under the
Amended COOL Measure. Moreover, the available evidence indicates that the
Amended COOL Measure is exacerbating the discriminatory impact of the original
COOL Measure. The impact of the Amended COOL Measure can be separated into two
categories of analysis: (i) the failure
to eliminate the discriminatory impact of the original measure and (ii) the
increase in discriminatory effects caused by the new regulations.
30. The Panel in the original proceedings undertook a detailed
examination of the impact of the COOL Measure on imported livestock. The Panel
found that competitive opportunities were reduced in significant ways. No
aspect of the new regulations is aimed at eliminating or reducing the burdens
and discriminatory impact of the COOL Measure. Thus, it is reasonable to assume that all of these instances of the
denial of competitive opportunities continue under the Amended COOL Measure.
31. For the second category of the impact analysis, the
three major areas in which increased effects are expected are (i) increased
requirements to segregate cattle of different nationalities; (ii) greater
reductions in the value of Mexican cattle resulting directly from the Amended
COOL Measure; and (iii) heightened disincentives to purchase Mexican cattle.
b. The Detrimental Impact Reflects Discrimination
against Imports
32. Based on the two-step approach of the AB in US-COOL,
the Panel must analyze whether the above-noted detrimental impact on imports
stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction rather than
reflecting discrimination against the group of imported products. In making
this determination, the Panel must carefully scrutinize the particular
circumstances of this dispute -the design, architecture, revealing structure,
operation, and application of the Amended COOL Measure- and, in particular,
whether it is even-handed, in order to determine whether it discriminates
against the group of imported products.
c. Relevant
Regulatory Distinctions
33. In conducting its assessment of the COOL Measure, the AB first
identified the relevant regulatory distinctions made by the COOL Measure,
namely the distinctions between the three production steps, as well as between
the types of country of origin labels that must be affixed to muscle cuts of
beef and pork. The Amended COOL Measure makes the same distinctions among the
three production steps.
34. The Panel must examine, based on the particular circumstances of
this dispute, whether the distinctions (i.e., born, raised and slaughtered) are
designed and applied in an even-handed manner, or whether they lack
even-handedness because, for example, they are designed or applied in a manner
that constitutes arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination.
35. The AB found that the COOL Measure is inconsistent with Article 2.1
on the basis that the regulatory distinctions imposed by the COOL Measure
amount to arbitrary and unjustifiable discrimination against imported
livestock, such that the distinctions could not be said to be applied in an
even-handed manner. On this basis, it found that the detrimental impact on
imported livestock did not stem exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction
but, instead, reflected discrimination in violation of Article 2.1. In
particular, the AB considered that the manner in which the COOL measure seeks
to provide information to consumers on origin, through the regulatory
distinctions described above, to be arbitrary, and the disproportionate burden
imposed on upstream producers and processors to be unjustifiable.
36. This finding was anchored in the AB's finding that the detrimental
impact caused by the COOL Measure could not be explained by the need to provide
origin information to consumers. This finding, in turn, was based on the
existence of two major information asymmetries between the origin information
collected and the origin information communicated to the consumer. First, the
COOL Measure did not impose labelling requirements for meat products that
provide consumers with origin information commensurate with the type of origin
information that upstream livestock producers and processors were required to
maintain and transmit. Second, information regarding the origin of all
livestock had to be identified, tracked, and transmitted along the chain of
production by upstream producers in accordance with the recordkeeping and
verification requirements of the COOL Measure, even though a considerable
proportion of the beef derived from this livestock was ultimately exempted from
the COOL requirements under the exclusions for processed food items, food
service establishments, and other establishments that are not a "retailer"
within the meaning of the COOL Measure.
d. The Distinctions
are not applied in an Even-Handed Manner
37. The factors raised by Mexico that demonstrate a lack of
even-handedness relate to the "facts and circumstances related to the
design and application of the relevant regulatory distinctions of the COOL
Measure" found by the AB.
38. In US -COOL, the AB applied its reasoning from US – Tuna II (Mexico) when it found that the COOL measure
modifies the conditions of competition in the U.S. market to the detriment of
imported livestock by creating an incentive in favour of processing exclusively
domestic livestock and a disincentive against handling imported livestock
(para. 292). The AB concluded that the original COOL Measure was not
even-handed because of the two information asymmetries. These information
asymmetries are "facts and circumstances" related to the design and
application of the "relevant regulatory distinctions". They are not,
in themselves, relevant regulatory
distinctions.
39. The two information asymmetries identified by the AB demonstrate the
expansive nature of the inquiry into the "facts and circumstances"
related to the design and application of the relevant regulatory distinctions. In
principle, every fact or circumstance that can demonstrate that the relevant
regulatory distinctions are not even-handed should be covered by this expansive
inquiry. The four additional factors raised by Mexico to demonstrate that the
measure is not even handed clearly fall within this scope.
e. Additional
factors that demonstrate that the Amended COOL Measure is not Even-Handed
40. In addition to the
two information asymmetries, Mexico identified four additional factors to
demonstrate that the discrimination is against imported products.
41. First, according to
the United States, a key justification for the COOL label is to avoid "consumer
confusion" it claims is caused by the USDA's own grade labelling system.
To the extent that the Amended COOL Measure is designed to override the
positive impression for beef products with a USDA Prime, Choice or Select label
when the product is made from imported cattle, the Amended COOL Measure is
intentionally discriminatory and not even-handed. Second, the Amended COOL
Measure maintains different labelling rules for different forms of beef, namely
muscle cuts of beef and ground beef. Specifically, it allows a processor to
reference a country of origin on its ground meat label even if the processor
has not had ground meat from that particular country in its inventory for the
last 60 days or less. Thus, the allegedly needed consumer information is
provided with the flexibility of a 60-day inventory allowance for ground beef
but with no inventory allowance for muscle cuts of beef. Third, "Trace-back",
a less trade restrictive alternative measure is prohibited under the Amended
COOL Measure. Such a system would accurately track information on where the
livestock contained in beef were born, raised and slaughtered, and it would do
so in a less trade restrictive manner. The Amended COOL Measure, like the COOL Measure, employs a certification and audit compliance mechanism that inherently shifts the costs of complying with the COOL Measure to
imported cattle. The fact that a trace-back alternative
is expressly prohibited demonstrates that the detrimental impact on imported
livestock does not stem exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction.
The exclusion is arbitrary and, because it prohibits the
substitution of the certification and audit compliance mechanism with a less
trade restrictive mechanism and even the simple consideration of such an
alternative, is evidence that the Amended COOL Measure
is a disguised restriction on international trade. It is therefore not even-handed.
42. Finally, only a very
small sub-set of U.S. consumers is interested in information on the origin of
beef. To the extent that the Amended COOL Measure mandates the communication of
origin information to a broader group of U.S. consumers, those additional
consumers will not pay any attention to the information and will not benefit
from it. The only beneficiary of this unnecessary additional coverage is the
U.S. cattle industry, which directly benefits from the discriminatory effects
of the measure. In this sense, this unnecessary additional coverage is further
evidence that the Amended COOL Measure is a disguised restriction on
international trade. It is therefore not even-handed.
43. For the above
reasons, the detrimental impact that continues to be caused by the Amended COOL
Measure cannot be explained or justified by the need to provide origin
information to consumers.
C. ARTICLE III:4 OF THE GATT 1994
44. The Amended COOL Measure accords Mexican cattle treatment less
favourable than that accorded to U.S. feeder cattle in a manner that is
inconsistent with Article III:4. The AB has made clear that the scope and
content of the provisions of Article III:4 and Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
are different. Accordingly, the Panel's decision on Mexico's claim under Article 2.1
will not necessarily resolve Mexico's Article III:4 claim, and it is
therefore crucial the Panel's findings on the Article III:4 claim.
45. In Korea – Various Measures on Beef, the AB explained that a Member's measure is inconsistent with Article III:4
if three elements are met: (i) the imported and domestic products at issue are "like
products"; (ii) the measure at issue is a law, regulation or requirement
affecting their internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation,
distribution, or use; and (iii) the imported products are accorded "less
favourable" treatment than that accorded to like domestic products.
1. Like Products
46. The imported and domestic products at issue (i.e., Mexican and U.S.
cattle) are like products.
2. Laws,
Regulations and Requirements Affecting Their Internal Sale, Offering for Sale,
Purchase, Transportation, Distribution or Use
47. Article III:4 applies to those "laws, regulations and
requirements" that affect "the internal sale, offering for sale,
purchase, transportation, distribution or use" of the products at issue.
The Amended COOL Measure, which comprises a group of laws and regulations that
set out the country of origin labeling requirement, pertains to the category of
"laws, regulations and requirements". These instruments include the
COOL Statute the 2009 Final Rule (AMS); and the 2013 Final Rule, which "affect
the internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution or
use" of feeder cattle.
3. Less Favourable Treatment
48. The collective effect of the four elements of the Amended COOL
Measure identified above (i.e., the mandatory requirement, the
born/raised/slaughtered requirement, the recordkeeping and verification requirement, and the
enforcement requirement) continue to deny competitive opportunities to imported
cattle. In particular, the failure of the Amended COOL Measure to eliminate the
various discriminatory effects of the original measure and the increase in
discriminatory effects caused by the new
regulations.
49. In the original proceedings, the Panel observed that in the absence
of a large share of US consumers willing to pay a price premium for country of
origin labelling, the cheapest way to comply with the COOL Measure is to
process only US-origin livestock, all other things being equal, that the other
possibility is to continue processing imported livestock through segregation,
which entails additional costs in virtually all cases and that either process
configuration is likely to cause a decrease in the volume and price of imported
livestock. Those effects continue under the Amended COOL Measure, and indeed
are becoming worse.
50. The Amended COOL Measure accords less favourable treatment to
Mexican cattle compared to U.S. cattle, providing U.S. cattle with a
competitive advantage in the U.S. market.
4. Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
and Article III:4 of the GATT
51. The United States and the European Union argue that the meaning
of "treatment no less favourable" should be the same in Article 2.1
and Article III:4. In their view, the two-step approach to determining
treatment no less favourable under Article 2.1 should be applied when
interpreting "treatment no less favourable" under Article III:4.
This interpretation is incorrect.
52. In the recent disputes US – Clove Cigarettes, US
– Tuna II and US –COOL, the
AB provided useful guidance on the relationship between the non-discrimination
provisions – Article 2.1 and Article III.4 –. The AB noted that both
provisions maintain some close similarities in terms of their language, but at
the same time recognized that "the scope and the content" of both
provisions are not the same.
53. Mexico's interpretation of Article III:4 follows the
interpretation developed in a long series of WTO and GATT 1947 reports i.e., a
measure confers less favourable treatment under Article III:4 where it
modifies conditions of competition in the relevant market to the detriment of
imported products compared to like domestic products. Therefore, in order to
analyze whether the amended COOL measure accords "less favorable treatment"
to imported livestock under GATT Article III:4, the only relevant inquiry
is whether the measure modifies the conditions of competition in the relevant
market to the detriment of the group of imported products vis-à-vis the group
of domestic like products.
D. THE AMENDED COOL MEASURE
IS INCONSISTENT WITH ARTICLE
2.2 OF THE TBT AGREEMENT
54. In ruling on the claims raised by Canada and Mexico under Article 2.2
in the original proceedings, the Panel found that the COOL measure is "trade-restrictive";
that the objective pursued by the United States through the COOL measure
is "to provide consumer information on origin" and that this
objective is "legitimate" within the meaning of Article 2.2. The
AB confirmed these findings.
55. Ultimately, the Panel found that the COOL measure does not fulfil the
identified objective within the meaning of Article 2.2 and therefore
violated Article 2.2. The AB reversed the ultimate finding and attempted
to complete the legal analysis under Article 2.2, but found it could not
do so because the Panel had not made relevant factual findings and there were
not sufficient uncontested facts.
56. In this proceeding, therefore, it is crucial that the
Panel make "clear and precise" findings, in particular, with respect to: (i) the Amended COOL Measure: the degree of its contribution to the
objective of providing consumers with information on origin, the degree of its
trade-restrictiveness, the relative importance of the
common interests or values furthered by the challenged measure, the nature of the risks at issue and the gravity of consequences
that would arise from non-fulfilment of the legitimate objective; and (ii) each proposed alternative measure: the degree of its contribution
to the objective of providing consumers with information on origin, taking
account of the risks non-fulfilment would create, the degree of its
trade-restrictiveness and whether it is reasonably available.
57. The United States
misinterprets the Panel's and the AB's findings when it states that the
objective pursued through the original COOL Measure was to provide consumers
with information on origin, namely, with respect to meat, where the animal was
born, raised and slaughtered. This misinterpretation should be rejected. The
original Panel and the AB found that the objective pursued by the United States
through the COOL Measure was "to provide consumer information on origin".
58. The new United States'
argument that the objective of the Amended COOL Measure is specifically to
provide information on where the livestock from which muscle cuts are produced
were born, raised and slaughtered is contradicted by the facts, including the
Amended COOL Measure itself. The United States attempts to redefine the
objective to an artificially narrow and self-serving one.
1. The Two-Step Necessity Test
under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement
59. Article 2.2 requires a two-step analysis: first, examination of
the measure at issue and second, comparison of this measure with the identified
alternative measures. The Panel
should objectively examine the trade-restrictiveness of the Amended COOL
Measure to determine whether it is "necessary", in itself and
independently of less trade restrictive alternative measures. Before moving to the second step of the
legal analysis and conducting an assessment of each proposed alternative
measure, the Panel should assess the Amended COOL Measure.
a. Application
of the First Step of the Necessity Test to the Amended COOL Measure
60. Under the first step of the necessity test,
the following factors are relevant to the weighing and balancing analysis in
respect of the Amended COOL Measure: (i) the "relative importance"
of the interests or values furthered by the Amended COOL Measure; (ii) the degree of contribution made
by the Amended COOL Measure to the legitimate objective at issue; (iii) the trade-restrictiveness of the
Amended COOL Measure; and (iv) the nature of the risks at issue and the gravity
of consequences that would arise from non-fulfilment of the objective(s)
pursued by the United States through the Amended COOL
Measure. In conducting this holistic analysis, the Panel should find that the
trade restrictiveness of the Amended COOL Measure is not necessary because it
is disproportionate to the risk
non-fulfilment would create.
61. The interests and values furthered by
the Amended COOL Measure fall on the low end of the spectrum of importance. The
relative importance of the provision of consumer information is substantially
lower than protecting the environment or protecting human beings from health
risks, both of which are vital and important in the highest degree; and
protecting public morals, which a panel observed ranks among the most important
values or interests pursued by Members as a matter of public policy.
Importantly, the interests or values furthered by the Amended COOL Measure are
not common. The USDA has acknowledged that
there is "interest by certain U.S.
consumers in information disclosing the countries of birth, raising and
slaughter on muscle cut product labels".
62. The following facts demonstrate that the Amended COOL Measure has a very
low degree of contribution to the objective of providing consumer information on origin: (i) the Panel and AB already determined that the labelling scheme for muscle
cuts under the COOL Measure did not provide clear and accurate information,
(ii) the Amended COOL Measure does not apply to all beef sold within the United States
because the measure's labelling requirements do not apply to all entities that
sell beef or to all beef products, the labeling requirements apply only to a
very limited portion of the meat products produced in the United States –
about 18 to 21 percent, (iii) like the COOL Measure, the Amended COOL Measure
continues to provide unclear, imperfect, or inaccurate information to
consumers, the information conveyed by the point of production information will
not in all cases be accurate. It is questionable whether consumers will
understand the meaning of a label that says "brn in Mexico, rsd and
slghtrd in US". The COOL information is normally printed in very small
typeface on labels, and often is on the bottom (rear) of the packaging; (iv)
Mexico is not aware of any information published by USDA to educate consumers
on what the COOL labelling information means.
63. The Amended COOL Measure does nothing to
eliminate these negative effects on competitive opportunities of imported livestock. The U.S. meat
processing industry has stated that the Amended COOL Measure, through its
prohibition of commingling, will increase the burdens of using imported cattle
even more. There will be increased burdens and effects relating to the need to
segregate, the application of the "COOL discount" to Mexican cattle,
and the disincentive to purchase Mexican cattle.
64. The risks at issue and the consequences that may arise from
non-fulfilment of the objective are certainly very minor, in light of the
following facts: (i) the COOL Measure is not a food safety measure, only a
small percentage of U.S. consumers are even aware of the measure, (ii) the meaning of the labels is unclear,
(iii) consumers value a label that says "Product of North America" at
least as much as a label that says "Product of United States, (iv)
the COOL Measure has not affected sales of meat products, (v) USDA itself sees little economic value in the COOL Measure and the
Amended COOL Measure, (vi) USDA has reported that a comprehensive
analysis of consumer reaction to COOL requirements for shrimp – implemented in
2005 – shows that COOL had no effect on consumer behavior.
65. In conducting the first step of the necessity
test, it is clear from these factors that the trade-restrictiveness of the
Amended COOL Measure is disproportionate to the risks that non-fulfilment would
create. The fact that the Amended COOL
Measure might make some contribution to the objective does not outweigh the
other relevant factors. Accordingly, the
trade-restrictiveness of the Amended COOL Measure is unnecessary and it is
inconsistent with Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
b. Application of the Second Step of the Necessity Test to the Amended
COOL Measure: Evaluation of the Alternative measures proposed by Mexico
66. If the Panel finds that the
trade-restrictiveness of the Amended COOL Measure is necessary, under the
second step, all relevant factors of each alternative measure are considered and a comparison is
undertaken between the challenged measure and each possible alternative
measure. The Panel must consider whether the proposed alternative is less trade
restrictive, whether it would make an equivalent contribution to the relevant
legitimate objective, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create,
and whether it is reasonably available.
67. As in the case of the COOL Measure, alternative measures exist that are less trade-restrictive than the
Amended COOL measure, make an equivalent contribution to the legitimate
objective of providing consumer information on origin taking account of the
risks non-fulfilment would create, and are reasonably available to the United States.
The alternatives are: (i) mandatory labeling based on a substantial
transformation rule of origin combined with voluntary labelling of specific
information (i.e., born, raised and slaughtered); (ii) mandatory labeling based
on the 60-day inventory allowance rule currently used for ground beef; (iii)
mandatory labelling of more specific information (i.e., born, raised and
slaughtered) using a "trace-back" system under which the precise
source of each animal and muscle cut must be traceable through the production process,
and (iv) a state/province labeling presented
by Canada and adopted by Mexico.
68. The first proposed alternative will
provide all consumers with mandatory required information on the origin of beef
products based on the substantive transformation rule and those consumers, who
are interested in further details, with voluntary information on where
livestock were born, raised and slaughtered. Under this alternative, the
exemptions of products (i.e., processed food items) and market segments (i.e., beef
sold in food service establishments and retailers) are eliminated, giving the
mandatory labelling element of this alternative labelling a broader scope of
application than the Amended COOL Measure. This alternative measure is not trade restrictive.
69. It would have a greater contribution
to the provision of origin information to consumers than the Amended COOL
Measure. At the very least, through the combination of mandatory and voluntary
labelling requirements, this alternative measure would make an equivalent
contribution to the objective of providing consumers with information on
origin, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create. A weighing and
balancing of the relevant factors of both the Amended COOL Measure and the
alternative measure demonstrates that compared to the challenged measure, this
alternative is less-trade restrictive and more proportionate to the risks
non-fulfilment would create. The voluntary labelling element of this
alternative is reasonably available and is used in the United States in
many other contexts.
70. The second proposed alternative is to extend the mandatory country of origin
labelling rule that is currently applied to
ground beef to apply to muscle cuts of beef and to processed food items made of beef. Under this alternative, the
exemptions of products (i.e., processed food items) and market segments (i.e.,
beef sold in food service establishments and small retailers) are eliminated,
giving the mandatory labelling a broader scope of application. For ground beef, the label must list all countries of origin contained
therein or that may be reasonably contained therein. In determining what is
considered reasonable, when a raw material from a specific origin is not in a
processor's inventory for more than 60 days, that country may no longer be
included as a possible country of origin. By
extending this rule to muscle cuts of beef and processed food items, such
products must be labeled in a manner that lists all countries of origin
contained therein or that may be reasonably contained therein in accordance
with the 60-day inventory allowance. The COOL
rules for ground beef are less trade restrictive than the Amended COOL Measure
for muscle cuts, because they provide more flexibility to cattle producers and
meat processors. Since the flexibility relates to the
inputs in meat processing, the same beneficial effects will occur if the ground
beef rules are applied to muscle cuts and processed food items. This
alternative is reasonably available. The ground beef requirement fulfils this objective for 40 percent of the beef products consumed in the United States, and there is no objective basis for
distinguishing between ground beef and muscle cuts and processed food items in this context.
71. The third proposed alternative measure is a trace-back system. During
the original proceedings, Mexico and Canada proposed a trace-back system as a
reasonably available less trade-restrictive alternative. This alternative would
accurately and comprehensively fulfil the
objective of the COOL Measure and yet not discriminate against imports in the sense that it would
eliminate the option of restricting trade in imports and as well as the option of discounting the price of imports as the most commercially viable option to comply with the Amended COOL Measure. Thus, costs of the mandatory labelling would be
spread evenly throughout the market. The employment of a trace-back system to
meet the objectives of the COOL measure is discussed in a paper written by
Dermot J. Hayes and Steve R. Meyer entitled Impact of Mandatory Country of
Origin Labeling on U.S. Pork Exports ("Hayes and Meyer Paper").
Although it focuses on pork, its analysis and conclusions apply equally to
beef. The authors discuss this system as a potential
method to implement COOL.
72. In Mexico's view, if there were trace-back system in place, there would be no incentive to exclude imported
Mexican cattle or shift the cost of compliance solely to Mexican animals. A mandatory trace-back alternative will provide detailed information on
where the animals were born, raised and slaughtered on all beef covered
commodities. The Hayes and Meyer Paper suggests that trace-back is technically and
economically feasible in the United States and, therefore, is a reasonably available alternative. Trace-back systems are used in the EU, Korea, Japan and other
countries. For example, Uruguay has implemented a comprehensive trace back system
which allows tracking livestock and the meat derived from those animals. The
Mexican system provides all the information needed for a trace-back system for
Mexican cattle. The applicable rules require that cattle exported to the United States
bear an ear-tag that can be used to trace the animal, including the State of
origin, the ranch which the cattle belongs to, and complete information about
its producer.
73. Finally, Canada presented a fourth
alternative measure which involves state/province labelling. Mexico
acknowledged to the Panel that Canada presented this fourth alterative measure
and Mexico endorsed and adopted this alternative by agreeing with Canada's
submissions on this alternative and the fact it (i) would provide a greater
contribution to the objective than the Amended COOL Measure, (ii) would be less
trade restrictive and (iii) is reasonably available. The arguments and evidence
that were endorsed and adopted by Mexico were presented by Canada in its Second
Written Submission. Given that Mexico and Canada have separately filed
submissions rather than a single joint submission, Mexico endorsed and adopted
the arguments and evidence at the first available opportunity in its Opening
Statement to the Panel. Thus, Mexico is clearly entitled to endorse and
incorporate the arguments and evidence of Canada pertaining to the third and
fourth alternative measures.
74. A weighing and balancing the relevant factors of both the Amended COOL
Measure and the alternative measure demonstrates that the Amended COOL Measure
is more trade-restrictive than necessary within the meaning of Article 2.2
and is, therefore, inconsistent with that provision.
2. Allocation of the Burden of Proof under Article 2.2
75. It is clear that, in addition to making a
prima facie case that the challenged measure is more trade restrictive than
necessary to achieve the contribution it make to the legitimate objective,
taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create, a complainant may seek
"to identify" a possible alternative measure. Mexico's burden is
simply to "identify possible alternatives", which it has done so. In
this dispute, Mexico has identified three possible alternative measures that
are less trade restrictive, make an equivalent contribution to the relevant
objective, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create, and are
reasonably available. The burden is on the United States to present
sufficient evidence and arguments showing that these alternative measures are
not less trade restrictive, do not make an equivalent contribution to the
objective pursued, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would crate and
are not reasonably available. The United States failed to do so.
3. The
Test of Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement is Not Applicable to Article 2.2
of the TBT Agreement
76. As in the original proceedings, the United States
attempts to incorporate Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement into Article 2.2
of the TBT Agreement, by arguing that the test of Article 2.2 was
equivalent to Article 5.6 and that an alternative measure should be significantly less trade restrictive as required by footnote
3 of Article 5.6. These arguments failed in the original proceedings. The
test described in paragraph 378 of the AB Report clearly indicates that: (i) Article 2.2
requires evaluation of the challenged measure, and in some cases a comparative
analysis with a proposed alternative; and (ii) when comparing with an
alternative measure, it may be relevant to consider "whether the proposed
alternative is less trade restrictive".
77. Second, Article 2.2 neither
contains the word "significant" nor a footnote similar to footnote 3
to Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement. Third, Article 1.4 of the SPS
Agreement provides that the different regimes, rules and the scope of
application of it and that of the TBT Agreement are mutually exclusive,
and therefore provisions of the SPS Agreement cannot be incorporated into the
provisions of the TBT Agreement. Fourth, with regard to the letter from
Peter D. Sutherland to John Schmidt on December 15, 1993, offered by the United States,
Mexico considers that it is not relevant because there
is no footnote in Article 2.2 that clarifies the meaning of the phrase "more
trade-restrictive than necessary". Such letter cannot be considered as a supplementary means of interpretation within
the meaning of Article 32 of the Vienna Convention on the
Law of Treaties.
E. ARTICLE
XXIII:1(B) (NON-VIOLATION NULLIFICATION OR IMPAIRMENT) OF THE GATT 1994
78. The Amended COOL
Measure nullifies or
impairs benefits accruing to Mexico based on tariff concessions made by the United States
in respect of live cattle at the end of successive multilateral rounds of trade
negotiations, in a manner that is inconsistent with Article XXIII:1(b).
79. The Panel in Japan – Film
dispute summarized the elements of a non-violation nullification and impairment
claim, and stated
that in order to make out a cognizable claim under Article XXIII:1(b) the complaining party
must demonstrate the following three elements: (i) an
application of any measure by a WTO Member; (ii) a benefit accruing under the relevant
agreement; and (iii) nullification
or impairment of the benefit as a result of the application of the measure.
80. The first element relates to the phrase "the application by
another Member of any measure", the word "any" indicates that Article XXIII:1(b)
does not distinguish between, or exclude, certain types of measures. The United States enacted and implemented
the COOL Measure and the Amended COOL Measure through a series
measures including statutory provision, regulations and other implementing
guidance, directives of policy announcements issued in relation to those
measures. The application of such measures by the United States meets this
element of Mexico's claim under Article XXIII:1(b).
81. The second element requires demonstrating the existence of a "benefit
accruing" to the complaining Member. This benefit can be measured in terms
of "legitimate expectations"
of improved market-access opportunities. An expectation is considered to be
legitimate if the challenged measure could not have been "reasonably
anticipated" at the time the tariff concession was negotiated.
82. Although the tariff concessions between Mexico and the United States
are currently based on the NAFTA, Mexico is entitled under Article XXIII:I(b)
to expect market access to the United States for its feeder cattle that is
related to the tariff concessions that would apply, on a Most-Favoured-Nation
(MFN) basis, between Mexico and the United States under the WTO Agreement.
The extent of the restrictions on market access resulting from the Amended COOL
Measure clearly could not have been expected. Mexico was entitled to expect for
exports of its feeder cattle.
83. The third
required element is that the benefit accruing to the WTO Member (e.g., improved
market access from tariff concessions) is nullified or impaired as the result
of the application of a measure by another WTO Member. In this sense, the Panel
affirmed that it must be demonstrated that the competitive position of the
imported products subject to and benefitting from a relevant market access (tariff)
concession is being upset by ("nullified or impaired ... as the result of")
the application of a measure not reasonably anticipated. Given the low U.S. MFN
rates in respect of feeder cattle, Mexico reasonably expected that its access
to the U.S. market for feeder cattle would be unrestricted. The Amended COOL
measure drastically restricts this access in a manner that could not have been
anticipated at the time of the conclusion of the Uruguay Round.
F. MEXICO'S CLAIM UNDER ARTICLE XXIII:1(B)
OF THE GATT 1994 IS WITHIN THE SCOPE OF THE PANEL'S TERMS OF REFERENCE
84. Mexico's non-violation nullification or impairment ("NVNI")
claim raised under Article XXIII:1(b) is within this Panel's terms of
reference in these Article 21.5 proceedings. The purpose of Article 21.5
proceedings is to resolve, on an expedited basis, "disagreement as to the
existence or consistency with a covered agreement of measures taken to comply
with the recommendations and rulings" adopted by the DSB. This mandate
encompasses claims by the complaining party that a measure "taken to
comply" is inconsistent with a covered agreement. A measure "taken to
comply" that results in the non-violation nullification or impairment of
any benefit which accrues to a party under the GATT 1994 is no less
inconsistent with the GATT 1994 than a measure which results in a
violation of one or more provisions. The mere existence and operation of Article XXIII:1(b)
indicates that the application of a measure does not need to result in a
violation of a provision of the GATT 1994 to be considered inconsistent
with the GATT 1994 if it nullifies or impairs a benefit accruing under the
GATT 1994. Hence, a claim to this effect under Article XXIII:1(b) is
entirely within the scope of Article 21.5 proceedings.
85. Article 26.1
of the DSU clearly
establishes that a panel or the AB has
jurisdiction to consider and resolve claims under Article XXIII:1(b), "whether
or not" the measure at issue conflicts with the provisions of the relevant
covered agreement, and provides additional guidance for circumstances in which
the measure at issue does not conflict with the provisions of the relevant
covered agreement.
IV. CONCLUSION
86. As Mexico has shown, the Amended COOL Measure is inconsistent with
the national treatment obligation under 2.1 of the TBT Agreement and Article III:4
of the GATT, also constitutes an unnecessary obstacle to trade in violation of Article 2.2.
of the TBT Agreement, and nullifies and impairs benefits accruing to
Mexico under the GATT 1994, within the meaning of Article XXIII:1(b).
United States has not brought itself into compliance with its obligations
through the adoption of the Amended COOL Measure.
ANNEX
B-3
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the united states
A. Complainants
Have Failed to Establish That the Amended COOL Measure Is Inconsistent with Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement
1. The United States has
taken a measure to comply that directly addresses the concerns in the Appellate
Body reports. The amended COOL measure increases the information provided and
sets out what is in effect a single label – disclosing the country of birth,
raising, and slaughter – for the three categories of meat that impact
complainants' livestock imports (i.e.,
categories A, B, and C). The single label affixed to those categories of meat
is even-handed. As such, any detrimental impact resulting from the amended COOL
measure now stems exclusively from legitimate regulatory distinctions.
2. What complainants primarily
contest, however, is a series of regulatory distinctions that has nothing to do
with the detrimental impact at all. The sum result of complainants' arguments
appears to be an attempt to convince the Panels that proof of a detrimental
impact alone proves a technical regulation to be discriminatory, despite the
Appellate Body's statements to the contrary. And, of course, this insistence
that a detrimental impact is enough to prove a technical regulation
discriminatory is the foundation of complainants' claim under GATT Article III:4.
3. Complainants' approach, if
successful, would render a great many regulatory measures vulnerable to WTO
challenge for the first time. All a complainant would need to prove to
successfully make a national treatment claim would be that a majority of the
domestic producers satisfy a particular standard, while a majority of the
complainants' producers do not, a fact pattern that surely repeats itself many
times over throughout the WTO membership.
4. However, the Appellate Body
has confirmed that technical regulations are not discriminatory where they draw
legitimate, even-handed regulatory distinctions, even where they
disproportionately impact the complaining party's producers. And complainants'
arguments fail on this very point. The regulatory distinctions made in the
amended COOL measure are, in fact, legitimate distinctions. In particular, the
label that is now affixed to A, B, and C meat explicitly references the
location where each of the three production steps took place, and provides
equally meaningful and accurate origin information for all three categories of
meat. Moreover, because the 2013 Final Rule eliminates the allowance for
commingling, the information provided for each of the three categories of meat
is equally accurate.
5. Complainants thus fail to
prove their case that any detrimental impact "reflect[s] discrimination." Accordingly, the amended COOL measure does
not accord less favorable treatment to imported livestock within the meaning of
Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement.
1. The
Complaining Parties Have Failed to Show That Any Detrimental Impact Caused by
the Amended COOL Measure Does Not Stem Exclusively From Legitimate Regulatory
Distinctions
a. DSB
Recommendations and Rulings Regarding Legitimate Regulatory Distinctions
6. To
prove that the measure accords less favorable treatment, and therefore
discriminates de facto against imports
from the complaining parties, complainants must prove that it "modifies
the conditions of competition in the relevant market to the detriment of the
group of imported products vis-à-vis the
group of like domestic products."
The Appellate Body has further clarified that a party must demonstrate
(1) that the measure has a "detrimental impact on imported livestock;"
and, if so, (2) that this detrimental impact does not stem exclusively from a
legitimate regulatory distinction, but rather reflects discrimination or a lack
of even-handedness. While the parties agree on that general framework, they
appear to agree on little else. In particular, the parties disagree as to (1)
which regulatory distinctions are relevant to the Article 2.1 analysis,
and (2) what analysis should be performed with regard to the relevant
regulatory distinctions.
7. As
to the first point, the Appellate Body has stated that because "technical
regulations are measures that, by their very nature, establish distinctions
between products according to their characteristics, or related processes and
production methods," not every distinction a measure makes is relevant to
the inquiry. Rather, "in an analysis under Article 2.1, we only need to examine the distinction that accounts for the
detrimental impact on [imported] products as compared to [domestic] products." As to the second point, the Appellate Body
has also been clear that a panel should examine whether the regulatory
distinction is "even-handed" or not.
8. Neither
complainant incorporates this analytical framework into their arguments. While
Canada "agrees that the regulatory distinction that must be examined to
determine the consistency with TBT Article 2.1
is the distinction that causes the
detrimental impact on imported products," Canada argues that that is not
the entirety of the analysis. Rather, Canada contends that "panels are not
precluded from considering elements of the challenged technical regulation that
do not specifically cause the detrimental impact but nevertheless demonstrate that the relevant regulatory distinction(s) reflect
discrimination." But the test is
not whether the relevant regulatory distinctions reflect discrimination, but
whether the detrimental impact reflects
discrimination – a point that the Appellate Body has made repeatedly. Canada
provides no support for its preferred analytic framework. Mexico ignores this
part of the analysis entirely.
9. Moreover,
complainants largely ignore whether the regulatory distinctions they focus on
are even-handed or not, preferring to criticize the distinctions as not
constituting "significant" enough change, or being "arbitrary,"
or that the information is not "intelligible." In so arguing, they appear to apply the wrong
test. The test under Article 2.1 is not whether
another Member thinks that the measure could be designed better, or more
clearly, or otherwise improved upon. The test is whether the measure treats
imported products less favorably than like products of another origin. And as
the Appellate Body has explained, this means whether any detrimental impact on
imported products stems exclusively from legitimate regulatory distinctions.
10. The question then is whether
the regulatory distinctions being made are legitimate, not whether the
technical regulation could, in the opinion of another Member, be better
designed.
b. The
Complaining Parties Fail to Establish a Prima Facie
Case That Any Detrimental Impact Caused by the Amended COOL Measure Does Not
Stem Exclusively From Legitimate Regulatory Distinctions
11. First, Canada wrongly argues
that the B and C labels have the "potential [for] inaccuracy" where
the animal "spends as little as 15 days in the United States"
and where animals "spend a short time in Canada prior to export for
slaughter in the United States."
12. Distinguishing between the
three stages of production necessarily entails defining when each stage ends. And
any definition will always be open to criticism that it could be done
differently or better, or that product on one side of the defined line between
stages is not sufficiently distinct from product on the other. Complainants
must rely on exotic hypotheticals because the new labeling requirements do, in
fact, provide the same accurate and meaningful origin information on A, B, and
C categories of meat resulting from animals actually being produced in the
three countries. But as to animals actually traded,
neither complainant disputes that the origin information provided regarding the
meat produced from feeder cattle actually traded is inaccurate (e.g., "Born in Mexico, Raised and Slaughtered in the
U.S."), and certainly not less accurate than the information provided for
A category meat. Similarly, Canada makes no claim that the origin information
provided for fed cattle actually traded (i.e., "Born
and Raised in Canada, Slaughtered in the United States") is
inaccurate, and certainly not less accurate than the information provided for A
category meat. The analysis should end there. The fact that complainants are
forced to rely on hypothetical scenarios not related to actual products being
traded and sold reveals that there is no basis for the complainants' de facto claims.
13. Of course, no actual
labeling situation will be able to address every hypothetical a clever lawyer
can invent, or every unusual circumstance that may occur. Rather, the labelling
system should address what is happening in the real world. And the amended COOL
measure does just that. The origin information regarding meat produced from all
(or virtually all) animals actually traded
by Canada and Mexico is as meaningful
and as accurate as the origin information
regarding A meat, and neither Canada nor
Mexico dispute that fact.
14. Second, Canada (but not
Mexico) contends that because B and C meat only constitute approximately a
third of the COOL labeled meat, any "new accurate information conveyed by
the amended COOL measure cannot be regarded as significant." By adding the production steps to the label
and eliminating the allowance for commingling, the amended COOL measure
provides a single label that provides for the same level of origin information
for A, B, and C category meat, which constitutes approximately 99.7 percent of
COOL labeled muscle cuts sold in the United States. The United States
has thus directly responded to the concerns in the Appellate Body reports
regarding the original COOL measure, which was not just limited to the B and C
labels, but included a concern that the previous A label did not explicitly
list the three production steps either.
15. Third, Mexico (but not
Canada) again argues that the labels being used by retailers to provide origin
information (both in terms of the size of the font and the abbreviations
allowed) does not provide "information that is accessible by or
intelligible to consumers." Mexico
makes no claim that that the label affixed to the B or C meat is less
intelligible than the label affixed to A meat. Indeed, Mexico and the United States
agree that a "single label" is now used to provide origin information
regarding A, B, and C category COOL-labelled meat. Accordingly, we understand
Mexico to concede that the design and application of the label itself is
even-handed. Further, Mexico does not establish a prima facie
case by merely making bare allegations that it "submits" are true.
16. Fourth, Mexico criticizes
the six month period of education and outreach that USDA provided for in the
2013 Final Rule, although it remains unclear what legal significance Mexico
attributes to its argument. However, Mexico does not appear to contest that the
six month period of education and outreach is even-handed (if, it could even be
considered a regulatory distinction at all). Mexico further concedes that
retailers are complying with the new rule and provides photographs from
retailers to prove this point.
17. Fifth, Canada argues,
incorrectly, that the elimination of the commingling will dramatically increase
the record keeping requirements and the overall detrimental impact on Canadian
livestock imports. To be clear, the United States has always taken the
position that the allowance of commingling reduced costs for those producers
that handle both U.S. origin and mixed origin animals or meat. However, as
discussed in the U.S. First Written 21.5 Submission, only three
beef processors, and zero pork
processors, stated for the record that they commingle different origin animals.
Accordingly, the administrative record of the 2013 Final Rule suggests that a
limited number of processors have been actually making use of this flexibility,
and that the adjustment costs due to the elimination of commingling are low. Notably,
Canada puts forward no evidence that any additional beef processors (other than
three already on the record) or any pork processors at all have been
commingling.
c. None
of the Complaining Parties' Other Criticisms Undermines the Conclusion That Any
Detrimental Impact Caused by the Amended COOL Measure Stems Exclusively From
Legitimate Regulatory Distinctions
18. First, it is clear that the
D Label is affixed to imported meat, and
therefore does not cause any detrimental impact on imported livestock. Neither complaining party contests this fact. It
should be quite clear, therefore, that any examination of the D Label will
simply not explain whether the detrimental impact on imported livestock
reflects discrimination. Moreover, Canada does not even allege – much less
prove – that the content of the D Label disadvantages Canadian producers
while benefiting U.S. producers. Indeed, Canada (and Mexico) believe the
opposite – that it is categories A, B, and C that disadvantage their producers,
not Category D.
19. Canada also argues that Label D
has the "potential to mislead consumers" where the meat was produced
from animals that were born and raised in a different country than the
exporting one. Yet imported meat is typically – if not always – produced
entirely within the exporting country as few countries around the world import
significant quantities of live cattle and hogs, and even fewer represent major
beef or pork suppliers to the United States. Canada is further unable to
say whether any meat derived from those imported cattle is actually exported
back into the United States (much less sold as D labeled-meat by a
retailer). Accordingly, Canada is forced to argue that the D Label merely
has the "potential to mislead consumers" because Canada has no evidence that the Canadian D labeled meat (i.e., "Product of Canada") is actually
misleading. It is clear that requiring the additional production step
information to be provided would not provide the consumer much, if any,
additional origin information as all (or virtually all) imported meat sold by
U.S. retailers will be derived from animals born, raised, and slaughtered in
the country denoted on the label (e.g., "Product
of Canada"). In other words, "Product of Canada" means, for all
practical purposes, "born, raised, and slaughtered in Canada."
20. Second, complainants argue
that the three exemptions from the COOL measure prove that the amended COOL
measure is discriminatory in that the detrimental impact does not stem
exclusively from legitimate regulatory distinctions. Neither party asserts that
the design and operation of the three exemptions has any nexus to any
detrimental impact. In fact, Canada affirmatively argues that such exemptions
do not cause the detrimental impact at all. As such, it would appear that all
parties agree with the original panel's finding that the "exact proportion
or magnitude of the exceptions and exclusions is irrelevant" for purposes
of the detrimental impact analysis. It is also clear that the exemptions
themselves are perfectly even-handed. That is to say, nothing in the design or
operation of the exemptions that define the scope of the amended COOL measure
disadvantage Canadian and Mexican livestock exports. Mexico also argues that
the exemptions prove that the amended COOL measure itself is not even-handed. But,
Mexico, like Canada, fails to explain why a measure that required small
businesses and restaurants to label their muscle cuts would make the measure,
as a whole, more even-handed in the measure's treatment of imported livestock
on the one hand and U.S. livestock on the other. The fact of the matter is that
it would not. Complainants also argue that the "disconnect" between
the amended COOL measure's "very limited coverage" and the upstream
costs of the amended COOL measure proves that the detrimental impact reflects
discrimination. Of course, neither Canada nor Mexico can explain why exemptions
that do not cause the detrimental impact, and are, themselves, entirely
even-handed, mean that the measure is discriminatory. The United States,
of course, disagrees with this approach – complainants must prove that the
detrimental impact reflects discrimination because it does not stem exclusively
from legitimate regulatory distinctions. Moreover, the coverage of COOL is
hardly limited. The measure constitutes a major policy decision to require over
30,000 grocery stores and other retailers throughout the United States to
provide country of origin information to their customers on the $38.5 billion
worth of beef and $8.0 billion worth of pork they sell annually.
21. Third, complainants argue
that the rules regarding ground meat (Category E) prove that rules for muscle
cuts are discriminatory without providing any basis for that argument. In fact,
the original panel has already found that the ground meat labeling rule does
not have a detrimental impact on imported livestock. As such, it simply cannot
be that any detrimental impact from the COOL measure stems from the ground meat
labeling rules. Further, USDA created the separate labeling rules for ground
meat based on the unique attributes regarding the production of ground meat,
which differs substantially from the production of muscle cuts. Canada also
contends that while it "is not challenging the consistency of the ground
meat label," it also claims that the ground meat label provides origin
information that "is far less detailed than that which is required to be
tracked and verified," and, therefore, not legitimate. The ground meat
rule does not cause a detrimental impact and therefore it is impossible to say
that the detrimental impact does not stem from a legitimate regulatory
distinction because the ground meat rule provides a different level of
information. Moreover, nothing about the ground meat rule could be said not to
be "even-handed." The rule
operates exactly the same – not only between the products of Canada, Mexico and
the United States, but between the products of all countries that are used
by U.S. ground meat producers.
22. Mexico appears to argue that
the ground meat rule does not provide consumer information on origin. Mexico is
wrong, of course. The ground meat rule does provide consumer information on
origin, but does so differently than the rules governing muscle cuts, a point
that Mexico itself concedes in the final sentence of its argument. Mexico also
argues that it is "arbitrary" for the United States to set forth
different origin labeling rules for ground meat than for muscle cuts. But Article 2.1
disciplines discriminatory measures, not arbitrary measures, and as discussed
above, the analysis of whether a measure provides less favorable treatment to
imported products does not call for an analysis of arbitrariness – standing
alone – as Mexico appears to contend.
23. Fourth, complainants argue
that the statutory prohibition of USDA implementing a "farm to fork"
traceability regime proves that the amended COOL measure is discriminatory. This
statutory provision (7 U.S.C. § 1638A(f)(1)) is an unchanged part of the
amended COOL measure, which does not cause any detrimental impact, and, as
such, is not relevant for purposes of this analysis.
24. Canada now argues that "the
prohibition [of a "farm to fork" traceability system], coupled with a
mandate for the Secretary of Agriculture to audit retailers to verify
compliance, necessitates the implementation of the amended COOL measure's
labelling requirements through the system of recordkeeping and verification
that is the cause of the detrimental impact on Canadian livestock." Mexico appears to take a similar position,
contending that "the prohibition is a disguised restriction on international
trade," and establishes that the entire measure "is not even-handed."
Again, the prohibition contained in 7 U.S.C. § 1638A(f)(1) is not the cause of
the detrimental impact. The original panel made no such finding, and neither
did the Appellate Body. Rather, the Appellate Body determined that the
detrimental impact stemmed from the distinctions between the production steps
and the distinctions between the different types of labels. Those distinctions
are set out in other parts of the statute and the 2009 Final Rule, and it is
those parts – not 7 U.S.C. § 1638A(f)(1) – that are relevant to this inquiry.
B. Complainants
Have Failed To Establish That the Amended COOL Measure is Inconsistent with Article III:4
of the GATT 1994
25. Despite arguing repeatedly
in the original proceeding that the national treatment provisions contained in
the TBT Agreement and the GATT 1994 should be given the same
interpretation, complainants now encourage these Panels to judge as to whether
the amended COOL measure is discriminatory under two entirely different legal
standards. For purposes of Article III:4, complainants contend that "treatment
no less favourable" is established solely based on proof that the
technical regulation results in a detrimental impact on imported products. This
analysis is incorrect.
26. The phrase "treatment
less favourable" as used in Article III:4 has always provided
regulatory space for the Member to take otherwise legitimate measures that may
restrict trade unevenly across the membership. Complainants disagree, arguing
that once a detrimental impact is established, the reasons underlying the
requirements of the technical regulation are irrelevant to the analysis. The
WTO has never adopted as narrow of an interpretation as complainants assert
here. It has long been understood that, consistent with Article III:4, "a
Member may draw distinctions between products
which have been found to be ‘like,' without, for this
reason alone, according to the group of ‘like' imported products
‘less favourable treatment' than that accorded to the group of ‘like' domestic
products." Thus, the existence of
distinctions between imported and domestic products is not enough. Any Article III:4
analysis must include an examination of whether such distinctions are evidence
that the measure is discriminatory or not. Given this, the Appellate Body's
approach to Article 2.1 is not surprising. The Appellate Body has noted: "the
two Agreements should be interpreted in a coherent and consistent manner"
in light of the fact that the Members intended the TBT Agreement "to
further the objectives of the GATT 1994."
27. Complainants argue that the sole relevant consideration is the effect of the measure. Any
examination of whether the technical regulation draws legitimate, even-handed
distinctions is deferred to the analysis of whether the "discrimination"
is "arbitrary or unjustified" under Article XX. Of course, for
technical regulations that pursue legitimate objectives not listed in Article XX,
the matter would end there. As to these measures, the question of whether a
measure is discriminatory turns only on whether a majority of the domestic
products satisfy a particular technical regulation, while a majority of the
like foreign products do not. A responding Member is simply not afforded the
opportunity to explain, nor would a panel have the ability to examine, the
underlying rationale and operation of the standard. The legitimacy – even the correctness – of the requirements is wholly
immaterial to the national treatment analysis.
28. Complainants' overly narrow
interpretation of Article III:4 greatly undermines a Member's ability to
regulate in the public interest, particularly where the Member pursues
legitimate governmental objectives not listed in Article XX. What
complainants' approach suggests is that a Member must, prior to applying a
technical regulation, survey all current and potential trading partners of
products affected by the measure to determine whether the affected products of
those countries either meet that standard (or whether its producers are willing
to adapt to the new standard). Where a particular country's products do not
meet that standard (and that country's producers are not willing to adapt), the
Member must lower its standards to avoid creating an
obstacle to trade. This "least common denominator" analysis approach
would undermine entirely the fact that the Member may take technical
regulations "necessary to achieve its legitimate objectives ‘at the levels it considers appropriate.'"
29. Each criticism of the U.S.
approach fails. First, Canada challenges that the United States has "no
textual basis" for claiming that the Article III:4 analysis "necessarily
entails an examination of whether the regulation makes distinctions that could
not be considered even-handed as to the group of ‘like' imported products
versus the group of ‘like' domestic products . . ." But what Canada ignores is that this
conclusion is built upon the Appellate Body's interpretation of the text of Article III.
Moreover, Canada is simply wrong to argue that the United States ignores
the context of the TBT Agreement and the GATT 1994. The context
supports the U.S. interpretation. While it is unquestioned that Article III:4
provides relevant context for the interpretation of Article 2.1, Article 2.1,
in fact, provides relevant context for the interpretation of Article III:4,
especially where the measure at issue is a technical
regulation.
30. Second, complainants
criticize the U.S. interpretation as trying to alter the "balance"
set out between Article III:4 and Article XX. The United States
is not contending that the Panel must "read into" Article III:4
an assessment of whether the discrimination is "arbitrary or
unjustifiable," as Canada alleges. Rather, what the United States is
saying is that the appropriate interpretation of whether
a technical regulation is discriminatory
must necessarily include an examination of the basis for the regulatory
distinctions that cause the detrimental impact. Furthermore, in light of their
view that Article 2.1 sets a much higher bar for a discrimination claim,
complainants fail to explain how their approach interprets the two agreements "in
a coherent and consistent manner."
Just the opposite would appear to be the case. Complainants'
artificially narrow interpretation of Article III:4 renders Article 2.1
a nullity.
31. The ultimate goal of
complainants is clear. While they no longer directly challenge the proposition
that providing consumer information on origin as to where the animal is born,
raised, and slaughtered is a legitimate governmental objective, complainants'
overly narrow construction of Article III:4 would prevent the United States
from doing just that, short of fundamentally altering how the entire U.S. meat
industry operates. To accept complainants' approach would be to accept that
there is no practical and reasonable way for the United States to provide
accurate origin information to its consumers, even where the meat was derived
from an animal that spent less than a day in the United States before
being slaughtered.
C. Complainants
Have Failed to Establish That the Amended COOL Measure is Inconsistent with Article 2.2
of the TBT Agreement
1. The DS386 Panel Should Reject Mexico's "Two
Step Necessity" Test
32. Mexico argues that the DS386
Panel should adopt a "two step necessity" test, comprising what
Mexico calls a "relational analysis" and a "comparative
analysis." Mexico fails to explain
why the Appellate Body did not engage in this "two step necessity"
test in the one dispute where it examined the merits of the claim, US – Tuna II (Mexico). Indeed, in US – Tuna II
(Mexico), the Appellate Body does not even acknowledge
the possibility of such an approach.
33. Mexico tries to ground its
approach in the fact that the Appellate Body acknowledges that there may be
instances where a comparison between the challenged measure and an alternative
measure would not be needed. But what Mexico cannot explain – and, in fact,
studiously ignores – is why the
Appellate Body determined in the original US – COOL proceeding that, in fact, the original panel should
have made this comparison. Indeed, the Appellate Body reversed the original
panel's Article 2.2 finding on this very point. It is clear that Mexico's "two
step" invention is designed to lessen its own burden of proof. Mexico was
quite explicit in this regard in its first submission, arguing that the DS386
Panel could find the amended COOL measure inconsistent with Article 2.2
without making a comparison to an alternative measure. Under Article 2.2
the complaining party must establish that an alternative measure exists that "is
less trade restrictive, makes an equivalent contribution to the relevant
objective, and is reasonably available."
The arguments by either complaining party that seek to relieve
themselves of any part of this burden should be rejected.
2. Factors
to Consider in Comparison Between the Amended COOL Measure and an Alternative
Measure
34. First, the objective of the
amended COOL measure was "to provide consumers with information on the
countries in which the livestock from which the meat they purchase is produced
were born, raised, and slaughtered," quoting the Appellate Body. Complainants
disagree, contending that the United States has taken the quote out of
context and that the Appellate Body made that statement in the context of
whether the objective was legitimate, and not in its identification. As such,
complainants appear to argue that the Appellate Body, in evaluating whether the
COOL measure's objective was legitimate, analyzed the wrong
objective. That is clearly incorrect. As the Panels are well aware, the
relevant objective can be stated in a number of ways. Certainly, it could be
stated as "to provide consumer information on origin," which is how
both the Appellate Body and the Panel has characterized it. Of course, that
same objective can be stated in more specific terms, such as how the Appellate
Body has also stated it. They are simply two formulations of the same objective.
Complainants disagree with the Appellate Body's formulation because that
formulation mentions the three production steps. Although they do not say so
directly, it would appear that complainants view such a formulation as
undermining their first two alternatives, neither of which provide much, if
any, origin information on the three production steps. Complainants would
simply prefer that providing consumers with information about the production
steps not factor into the analysis.
35. But this is where the flaw
of complainants' approach is truly exposed. For the real issue is not what the
objective is – that has been decided – but, as the Appellate Body explains,
what "is the degree of contribution to the objective that a measure actually achieves."
And what the amended COOL measure actually achieves
is that it provides meaningful and accurate information on origin for muscle
cuts sold at retail as to where the animal was born, raised, and slaughtered. It
is thus immaterial whether the objective is characterized as "to provide
consumer information on origin," on the one hand, or it is "to
provide consumers with information on the countries in which the livestock from
which the meat they purchase is produced were born, raised, and slaughtered,"
on the other. The degree of contribution to the objective that the measure
actually achieves is the same under
either formulation.
36. Second, Canada and
(sometimes) Mexico continue to equate the phrase "less trade restrictive"
with the phrase "less discriminatory." The term "trade restrictive" "means
something having a limiting effect on trade." Accordingly, the Appellate Body in US – Tuna II (Mexico) concluded that "Article 2.2
does not prohibit measures that have any trade-restrictive effect. It refers to
‘unnecessary obstacles' to trade and thus allows for some
trade-restrictiveness …" In light
of that guidance, it simply cannot be that Article 2.2 allows for some discrimination. Indeed, the Appellate Body's statement
that what Article 2.2 disciplines is "trade-restrictive effect"
only makes sense when "trade restrictive" is understood to refer to
limiting trade effects, i.e., limiting
market access.
37. Canada requests that the
DS384 Panel "be sufficiently flexible" in its interpretation of the
agreement "to account for elements that are difficult to quantify, such as
practical difficulties in selling or handling imported products" under the
amended COOL measure. Yet the difficult question here is not what the trade
effects of the amended COOL measure are. The question is what will be the trade
effects of the "farm to fork" traceability regime, and it is that
burden that complainants fail to meet.
38. Mexico attempts to lessen
its burden by contending that it does not have the burden of proof with regard
to any alternative measures it proposes. Canada appears to take a similar,
albeit more limited approach, contending that it should not have to carry this
burden where it is difficult to do so. Yet the Appellate Body has been clear on
this point – the allocation of the burden of proof does not depend on how
difficult it is for the complainant to prove its case.
39. The United States
agrees with Canada that it may very well be difficult to establish that a "farm
to fork" traceability regime (or the state/province alternative) is
actually less trade restrictive than the amended COOL measure. The reason for
this is fairly obvious – determining how a complicated regulatory mechanism
would affect the complex U.S. livestock and meat industries is not easily done.
Indeed, Canada may understand this problem better than most, given that it has
failed to completely implement its own "farm to fork" traceability
regime in Canada despite examining the issue for over a decade. But this is the
complainants' burden.
40. Third, complainants appear
to accept the framework for evaluating whether a measure could be considered to
be "reasonably available."
However, neither party satisfies its burden in this regard, particularly
with regard to the "farm to fork" traceability alternative and
state/province designation alternative.
3. The
Complaining Parties Have Failed to Establish a Prima Facie
Case That an Alternative Measure Exists That Proves the Amended COOL Measure Is
Inconsistent With Article 2.2
a. The
Burden of Proof
41. Mexico contends that it does not have the
burden of proving that an alternative measure exists that establishes that the
amended COOL measure is inconsistent with Article 2.2. Mexico's position
directly contradicts its own position
before the Appellate Body in this very dispute where it accepted that, as a
complainant, it is Mexico that carries "the
burden of proof with respect to such alternative measures." It has been long understood that complainants
carry the burden of proof for their claims under those rules, and respondents
carry the burden of proof for their affirmative defenses. Mexico's argument is
just the latest attempt by the complainants to relieve themselves of their own
burden of proof. The United States requests both Panels to reject
arguments of the complaining parties that seek to relieve themselves of their
own burden.
b. First
Alternative Measure
42. The design, structure, and
operation of the amended COOL measure indicates that the degree to which it actually contributes to its objective of providing consumer
information on origin: it provides
meaningful and accurate information on origin for muscle cuts sold at retail as
to where the animal was born, raised, and slaughtered. Alternative measures
that contribute to the objective at a lesser degree do not prove a challenged measure
inconsistent with Article 2.2. This is the only logical interpretation of
the TBT Agreement whose 6th preambular recital acknowledges
that the Member "shall not be prevented from taking measures necessary to
achieve its legitimate objectives ‘at the levels it considers
appropriate,'" a point that the Appellate Body has repeatedly
emphasized. Complainants' analyses are directly contradictory to both the
applicable agreement and the Appellate Body's interpretation of that agreement.
Complainants' proposed first alternative unquestionably fails the legal test of
Article 2.2.
43. Rather than acknowledging
these problems directly, complainants discuss the labeling differences between
Categories A, B, and C, on the one hand, and Categories D and E, on the other. First,
Canada appears to argue that they have satisfied their own burden of proof
because the United States "has not
explained why it considers that Label D and Label E fulfil its
objective." Notwithstanding the
obvious burden of proof problem, what should be obvious to all participants in
this dispute is that this is not the test for Article 2.2 – none of the parties need to prove that a label does or does
not "fulfill" the U.S. objective in the abstract. The question is
rather, whether complainants have established a prima facie
case that an alternative measure exists "that is less trade restrictive,
makes an equivalent contribution to the relevant objective, and is reasonably
available." Second, Mexico argues
that "[t]he United States has not provided a basis for distinguishing
consumers' desires for origin information as between muscle cuts, ground beef
and imported meat products." But
again Mexico, like Canada, fails to explain how the existence or non-existence
of such a basis is relevant to the required prima facie
case for this claim. Third, the phrase "risks non-fulfilment would create"
does not provide a different conclusion. What complainants are essentially
arguing here is that the objective of consumer information is simply not "legitimate"
or "important" enough to rebut an Article 2.2 challenge. As
should be clear, the United States considers that providing consumers with
this information is very important. And nothing in the TBT Agreement
generally, or Article 2.2, requires the United States to re-order its
objectives to conform to the policy priorities of its trading partners.
c. Second
Alternative Measure
44. Complainants continue to
maintain that applying the ground meat rules to all muscle cuts without
exemptions proves the amended COOL measure inconsistent with Article 2.2. This
argument is in error. The ground meat rules provide limited origin information
as to where the animal was born, raised, and slaughtered, and, therefore,
cannot be considered to make an equivalent contribution to the objective that
the amended COOL measure does – namely, to provide meaningful and accurate
information on origin for muscle cuts sold at retail as to where the animal was
born, raised, and slaughtered.
d. Third Alternative Measure
45. Third, complainants maintain
that the alternative of a "farm to fork" traceability regime proves
the amended COOL measure inconsistent with Article 2.2. This argument is
in error. A complaining party does not discharge its burden of proof by putting
forward an alternative that is "merely theoretical in nature." The party must base its alternative on "sufficient
evidence," which "substantiat[es] the likely nature or magnitude of
the costs that would be associated with the proposed alternative, as compared
to the current system." Bare
allegations that the Member could adopt the alternative are simply not enough
to establish a prima facie case.
46. Canada
now argues that "farm to fork" traceability is less trade restrictive
for two reasons: 1) the alternative is
non-discriminatory; and 2) the alternative "could not possibly entail"
the same costs that the amended COOL measure does with respect to Canadian
producers. Canada continues to decline to examine what effects a "farm to
fork" traceability system would actually have on trade. Mexico provides no
additional timely evidence, simply alleging that such a system "would not
impose material new costs on Mexican producers."
47. As to Canada's first
argument, the TBT Agreement cannot be read to mean that a "less trade
restrictive" measure is one that is simply "less discriminatory." Rather, a "less trade restrictive"
measure is one that will permit greater market access for goods than the
challenged measure. Moreover, in EC – Seals,
Canada appears to agree with the United States that trade flows, not
discrimination, is the touchstone of trade restrictiveness.
48. As explained previously, the
central question here is what effect the adoption of this alternative will have
on trade. And as to this central question, neither complainant even alleges that trade would increase under a trace-back
regime.
49. As to Canada's second
argument, Canada relies on Dr. Sumner's analyses of the original COOL regime,
which Canada claims to prove a "farm to fork" traceability regime to
be less trade restrictive because it "could not possibly entail" the
same amount of costs to Canadian industry as the original COOL measure has
allegedly imposed, an impact which Dr. Sumner estimates to be the equivalent of
increasing processing and marketing costs by $608 per head of cattle and $116
per hog on all livestock processed in the United States. However, the
conclusions drawn from the previous econometric models are not credible, highly
inflated (to say the least), and suffer from numerous data and methodological
shortcomings.
50. However, even setting aside
the inaccuracies and discrepancies, then Dr. Sumner's conclusions should be
readily observable in today's market for Canadian cattle in the United States,
given that the original COOL measure is imposing costs of approximately $600
per head, in the form of increased processing and marketing costs, on Canadian
exported cattle. Under these circumstances, one would expect to see drastic
differences between Canadian and U.S. steer prices to account for such an
effect. To the contrary, there has been minimal change between the prices and
the difference between them has actually narrowed.
51. Given these minimal changes
in Canadian steer prices in respect of U.S. steer prices, Dr. Sumner's model,
if appropriate, implies that Canadian cattle producers and U.S. packers and
feedlots purchasing Canadian livestock are internalizing the majority of the
estimated equivalent costs (which, according to Dr. Sumner, at a minimum, are
equivalent to 39 percent of the average wholesale steer price). But to do so
would be prohibitively expensive and should cause the Canadian live cattle
export market to the United States to disappear entirely. But this is not
occurring. In fact, the quantity and price of cattle exported from Canada into
the United States has remained relatively consistent, accounting for
normal fluctuations since the implementation of the 2009 Final Rule. In short,
Dr. Sumner's analysis is simply not credible and is not borne out by the facts
and data in the market.
52. Mexico's "adoption"
of Dr. Sumner's calculations contained in CDA-126 were untimely, and
inconsistent with paragraph 7 of the Working Procedures of the Panel and DSU Article 12.4.
53. While complainants appear to
accept the Appellate Body's view in US – Gambling
that an alternative measure is not "reasonably available" where it "imposes
an undue burden on that Member, such as prohibitive costs or substantial
technical difficulties," neither complainant provides any evidence to establish
a prima facie case that the measure is, in
fact, reasonably available.
54. First, Mexico contends that
it does not shoulder the burden in this regard, and (presumably) in light of
that position, provides no additional cost analysis, nor responds to any of the
U.S. criticisms of the sole piece of evidence that Mexico relies on, the ten
year old Hayes & Meyer article. As discussed above, it is clear that
Mexico, as the complaining party, has the burden of proof with regard to the
alternatives it proposes. It is equally clear that Mexico has failed to satisfy
that burden of proof.
55. Second, while Canada appears
to accept that it has the burden of proof to prove that a "farm to fork"
traceability regime is "reasonably available," Canada does not put forward
sufficient evidence to establish a prima facie
case in this regard, relying solely on a cost estimate done in relation to the
NAIS.
56. As to the costs of the
alternative itself, as noted above, Canada misleadingly relies on a cost
analysis commissioned by APHIS and performed by a consortium of non-government
researchers in connection with the NAIS. The NAIS Study did not evaluate a
trace-back system from farm to retail. Rather,
it only evaluated traceability up to the point of slaughter,
since it was focused on animal disease status, not consumer information. Yet
the implementation of animal traceability would create heavy costs after the
animal has been slaughtered at the processing and retail levels where workers
are forced to keep meat from each animal segregated and attached to data
generated at the farm and intermediary production steps. As such, it is clear
that Canada has not put forward a complete cost analysis.
57. USDA has never produced an
analysis of the costs of implementing a farm to retail trace-back regime for
beef and pork, and, as discussed above, it is not the U.S. burden to do so for
purposes of this proceeding. As is clear, however, the costs of implementing
such a regime would be high indeed, and would likely have dramatic effects on
the industry. By moving from a COOL regime to a traceability regime that is
concerned with the life history of each animal, animals are forced to move in
batches of one animal (i.e., animal by
animal) through the slaughter facility, in the packaging process, and at the
retail level, as meat cutters are forced to segregate each animal and the meat
for each animal from other animals to ensure the label finally placed at retail
has accurate detailed information about place of birth, development, and slaughter.
Those procedures would require dramatic slowdowns in the meat cutting process,
and would add substantial burdens to retailers and other vendors who must
associate particular cuts of meat with labels that correspond to the individual
animal. In this regard, the U.S. industry differs greatly from the two examples
Canada cites to, Japan and Uruguay, both of which have much smaller industries
than the United States does.
58. It is, of course, telling
that Canada cannot cite itself as an
example of a country that has implemented a "farm to fork"
traceability regime, despite studying the issue since 2003. All Canada can say
is that it and its stakeholders "are working towards a practical phased-in
strategy for tracking animal movements."
The fact that Canada has been "working towards" full national
traceability for over a decade now, without being able to implement (or even
being able to state when it will
implement), underscores just how difficult it is for a country to implement
this extremely expensive system. And if that is true for Canada then it means
it will be even more true for the United States, which has much larger
herds than does Canada, and whose individual animals appear to move much more
frequently domestically than do Canadian animals.
e. Fourth
Alternative Measure
59. Canada puts forward a fourth
alternative measure: a labeling regime
whereby the label would inform consumers as to the state or province from which
an animal was born, raised, and slaughtered. Canada puts forward no (or virtually
no) evidence to support this alternative, and it is abundantly clear that
Canada has not established a prima facie
case that that this alternative proves that the amended COOL measure is
inconsistent with Article 2.2. Canada merely alleges, without support,
that the alternative would provide a "greater degree of fulfillment"
than the amended COOL measure and would be less trade-restrictive. Importantly,
however, it does not appear to the United States that this alternative is
any more reasonably available or any less trade-restrictive than the "farm
to fork" traceability regime. As such, the United States considers
that this alternative does not present an entirely new alternative at all.
60. Cattle production in the United States
is widely dispersed throughout the entire country. However, because it is often
less expensive to move animals than feed, the U.S. industry is characterized by
a large amount of interstate movement of animals. This is particularly true for
cattle, 57 percent of which move interstate, but it is true for hogs as well. As
such, the U.S. industry has evolved such that different regions of the country
have specialized in certain aspects of livestock production system. As an
individual cow moves through its lifecycle it would not be unusual for it to
move through multiple states as it goes to different specialized feed lots, etc.
Moreover, the overwhelming majority of cattle (85 percent) are sold and resold
in local auctions, often several times, where they are "sorted and mixed with
calves from other areas before ultimately arriving at pastures or feedlots." This repeated intermingling of cattle from
different states between multiple auction houses commonplace within the cattle
industry would necessitate that each individual head of cattle be tracked as it
goes through the livestock production process. As such, it would appear to the United States
that the recordkeeping that would need to be required in any such system would
need to track the individual animal, no different from the "farm to fork"
traceability system.
61. We do note, however, that
U.S. cattle production is in stark contrast to Canadian cattle production,
which is highly concentrated in Western Canada, with nearly 86.6 percent of all
beef cows within this region. Additionally, the remaining cattle not produced
in Western Canada are exceptionally concentrated, with 91 percent of all beef
cattle raised in Eastern Canada occurring in the provinces Ontario and Quebec. It
does not appear to the United States that there is the same amount of
inter-province movement of cattle (or hogs) as there is in the United States.
62. Mexico's "adoption"
of this argument was untimely, and inconsistent with paragraph 7 of the Working
Procedures of the Panel and Article 12.4 of the DSU.
D. Complainant's
Claims Under Article XXIII:(1)(b) of the GATT 1994 Are Outside the
Terms of Reference of these Panels and Otherwise Fail
1. NVNI Claims Are Outside the Terms of
Reference of These Proceedings
63. Under the plain text of DSU Article 21.5,
the terms of reference of a compliance panel do not include a claim that a
measure taken to comply causes NVNI. This is because the questions presented
are either: (1) whether a measure taken
to comply exists (an issue not presented in the current proceeding); or (2)
whether a measure taken to comply is inconsistent with a covered agreement. The
first question is inapplicable in this case since the United States has
taken a measure to comply. The second question by definition concerns the
inconsistency of a measure, and therefore excludes a claim of NVNI.
64. Complainants respond that "‘consistency' can have a meaning that is broader than a violation or infringement of a covered
agreement" or, perhaps even more surprisingly,
that a "measure ‘taken to comply' that results in the non-violation
nullification or impairment of any benefit which accrues to a party under the GATT 1994
is no less inconsistent with the GATT 1994
than a measure which results in a violation of one or more provisions." Neither approach can be reconciled with the
text of the DSU or with the complainants' own claims.
65. DSU
Articles 19.1 and 26.1(b) make clear that if a measure is inconsistent
with the covered agreements, then Article 19.1 applies and Article 26.1(b)
does not, and the converse is also true. Contrary to what the complainants
assert, the term "inconsistent" does not encompass measures that are
both consistent and inconsistent with the covered agreements.
66. The NVNI claims of the
complainants appear to be claims in the alternative. Essentially, the
complainants are claiming that, if the Panels find that the amended COOL
measure is not inconsistent with one of the provisions of a covered agreement
cited by a complainant in its panel request, then the amended COOL measure
nonetheless nullifies or impairs the benefits of Canada or Mexico. However,
complainants' own claims demonstrate that their NVNI claims do not involve a "disagreement
as to the … consistency with a covered agreement of measures taken to comply." Rather, at the point their NVNI claims would
become relevant, there is no longer a disagreement as to consistency, and the
issue involves instead the issue of whether, despite the lack of any
inconsistency, the amended COOL measure nullifies or impairs benefits. This
latter question is not within the terms of reference of Article 21.5 of
the DSU.
2. Complainants' NVNI Claims Otherwise Fail
67. Complainants appear to agree
that they need to demonstrate that the amended COOL measure nullifies or
impairs benefits accruing to them under the WTO Agreement. However, they
fundamentally misunderstand what this demonstration entails. First, they have
only generally referred to "tariff concessions" under the GATT 1994
without ever specifying what they are in detail. This general reference is not
sufficient to meet the requirement in Article 26.1(a) that "the
complaining party shall present a detailed justification in support of any
complaint relating to a measure which does not conflict with the relevant
covered agreement."
68. But even more importantly,
the complainants do not explain how the amended COOL measure can nullify or
impair any benefits under these unspecified tariff concessions when they
concede that currently their trade is governed by, and benefitting from, tariff
concessions under the NAFTA. If their trade is not benefitting from WTO tariff
concessions, then the benefits under those tariff concessions are being neither
nullified nor impaired.
69. Complainants also appear to
misunderstand the aspect of an NVNI claim relating to reasonable expectations. Complainants
state that they could not have anticipated the "upset of the competitive
relationship" or "a change to the labelling regime that is designed
and implemented in a manner which results in severe discriminatory treatment
and the modification of competitive opportunities in the U.S. market to the
detriment of Mexican cattle." In
both cases, however, complainants appear to be arguing that they did not
anticipate a measure in breach of the covered agreements. This argument does
not, however, address NVNI claims.
70. Furthermore, the
complainants do not address the evidence put forward by the United States
that the complainants had a reasonable expectation that the United States
could require more information be provided to consumers as to the origin of the
meat they purchased.
_______________
ANNEX C
Arguments
of Third Parties
Contents
|
Page
|
Annex C-1
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Brazil
|
C-2
|
Annex C-2
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of China
|
C-4
|
Annex C-3
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Colombia
|
C-7
|
Annex C-4
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the European Union
|
C-10
|
Annex C-5
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of India
|
C-15
|
Annex C-6
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of Japan
|
C-18
|
Annex C-7
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the Republic of Korea
|
C-24
|
Annex C-8
|
Integrated
executive summary of the arguments of New Zealand
|
C-26
|
ANNEX C-1
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of brazil
1. Brazil
hereby presents its integrated executive summary, where it provides a brief
description of the main points it submitted to the Panel in its Third Party
Submission and Oral Statement.
(a) The
legitimacy of the objective of a technical regulation does not constitute a
waiver to illegitimate regulatory discrimination that is detrimental to the
conditions of competition of imported products
2. Brazil agrees that in the pursuit of a legitimate objective, adopted
technical regulations may have an adverse impact on imports inasmuch as
compliance with such regulations is mandatory. Accordingly, it has been
clarified that Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
does not prohibit measures that result in a detrimental impact on imports,
provided that such impact stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory
distinction.[5] However, in Brazil's understanding, the fact that the objective of the
measure is legitimate has no bearing on the determination of the legitimacy of
the regulatory distinction under Article 2.1 of the TBT.[6] Rather, the legitimacy and the legality of the distinction itself must
be assessed separately.
3. In addition, for the assessment of the consistency of the measure taken
to comply with Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement,
Brazil recalls the approach taken by the Appellate Body in the original
proceeding. While verifying whether a treatment no less favorable is accorded
to like imported products, it is relevant to consider the effect of the measure on the competitive opportunities in the
market.[7] As Brazil stated in its Third Party
Submission, the market conditions prevailing before and after the measure taken
to comply can be informative to such assessment.
(b) The
assessment on whether a technical regulation is no more trade restrictive than
necessary must encompass not only the analysis of the intrinsic features of the
measure, but also a comparative analysis of other available substitutable
measures.
4. While
assessing whether the changes in the COOL measure contributed to restore the
aforementioned conditions of competition, the Panel may also look into its
effects on international trade, in light of Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
5. As
the Appellate Body has already stated, the determination of whether a measure
is more restrictive to trade than necessary involves a process of weighting and
balancing a series of factors, including the impact of the regulation on
imports or exports.[8] In addition, a comparison with reasonably available alternative
measures is a conceptual tool for the purpose of ascertaining whether a
challenged measure is more trade restrictive than necessary in the light of the
nature of the risks at issue and the gravity of the consequences that would
arise from non-fulfilment of the legitimate objective.[9]
6. Once
a measure is found to genuinely contribute to the fulfilment of its legitimate
policy objectives, the analysis should turn to the effects of the measure
itself, taking into account the contribution it makes to the objective and the
risks that the non-fulfilment of the objective would create. Brazil agrees with
the Parties that this assessment cannot be done in abstract; rather, it has to
be discerned from the design and operation of the measure itself. This involves
necessarily an analysis of ends and means and, from the comparison between ends
and means and less trade-restrictive alternatives, what could be considered
technically and economically feasible.
7. Assuming
that the COOL measure, if properly applied, could contribute to the legitimate
objective of providing meaningful information to consumers, the focus of the
inquiry, in the context of an Article 21.5 panel procedure, should be on
whether the changes introduced in the measure by the United States can
achieve this very objective in a manner consistent with the DSB recommendations
and rulings. The changes must ensure that the same conditions of competition
prevail between imported and national products. The degree of
trade-restrictiveness of the amended COOL measure may serve as useful guidance
to the panel's assessment.
(c) The scope of compliance proceedings
includes not only newly adopted
measures, but also any unmodified part of the original challenged
measure
8.
Brazil understands that compliance with DSB's recommendations and rulings must
be assessed through the examination of the measures taken to comply broadly
understood, i.e. including not only new administrative and legal measures but
also omissions and relevant measures in force before the adoption of the
report(s) by the DSB. This means that such assessment must encompass the
effects of both the amendments and the unaltered parts of the original
challenged measure as they operate jointly.
9. Were unaltered parts of the original challenged measure outside the
jurisdiction of the compliance panel, this would mean that the responding party
would be able to circumvent the DSB's
recommendations and rulings by complying with only selected parts of challenged
measures, while evading compliance with all the rest, as these would be immune
to further challenge.[10]
ANNEX C-2
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of china
1. Whether
the Amended COOL measure is consistent with Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
- Exemptions Granted by the Amended COOL Measure
1. In the original
proceeding, the Appellate Body found "the Panel's legal approach to
assessing detrimental impact was correct",[11] but the Panel shall not
end its analysis under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement there, and
leave its legal analysis under Article 2.1 incomplete. Instead, "the
Panel should have continued its examination and determined whether the
circumstances of this case indicate that the detrimental impact stems
exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction, or whether the COOL
measure lacks even-handedness".[12]
2. The Appellate Body
further stated that "A regulatory distinction is not designed and applied
in an even-handed manner—for example, because it is designed or applied in a
manner that constitutes a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
discrimination—that distinction cannot be considered legitimate and, thus, the
detrimental impact will reflect discrimination prohibited under Article 2.1."[13]
3. China understands
there are two respects of fact leading to the conclusion of the Appellate Body
that regulatory distinctions imposed by the COOL measure are arbitrary and
unjustifiable: (1) prescribed labels do not expressly identify specific
production steps, in particular for Labels B and C; (2) considerable proportion
of beef and pork is exempted from the COOL requirements.
4. As demonstrated by
the complaining parties, it seems that the Amended COOL Measure does not
address the scope of the extensive exemptions to the COOL measure in any way,
the only modification is a slight change to the definition of
"retailer" to include any person subject to be licensed as a retailer
under the PACA.[14] The US itself does not contend this argument,
and the US admits that the Amended COOL measure "makes no change to the
scope of the COOL measure".[15]
5. In its first
written submission, the US provided three arguments to prove that revising the
scope of the COOL measure is not necessary, which China does not agree.
6. Firstly, the US relies on the finding of the Panel that the exemptions
that define the scope of the Amended COOL measure were
simply "irrelevant" to the detrimental impact analysis.[16]However, the US seems to
ignore the fact that the Appellate Body has revised the reasoning of the Panel
as to Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement, and it made extensive
findings in terms of the scope of the COOL measure. Contrary to the US's
argument, the Appellate Body emphasizes that "this lack of correspondence
between the recordkeeping and verification requirements, on the one hand, and the
limited consumer information conveyed through the retail labelling requirements
and exemptions therefrom, on the other hand, is of central importance to our
overall analysis under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement".[17]
7. Secondly, the US
argues that the challenged measure is not unusual at all – in fact it is firmly
in the majority, since even the complaining parties' own COOL measures do have
limitations.[18] This logic is
problematic. If the US believes that measures of other complaining parties also
accorded less favorable treatments to the imported product from the US than
those domestic products, it is entitled to challenge, as it often did in the
past, in the dispute settlement procedure. Nevertheless, the fact that other
WTO Members keep similar measures can not be an excuse for the US to adopt
measures violating its WTO obligations, no matter to what extent those measures
are "similar".
8. Thirdly, the US argues that
the statistics provided by the complainants are not correct. As demonstrated by
the complaining parties, the Amended COOL Measure provides
information to consumers on only 30% of the U.S. beef supply and on 11% of this
pork supply – figures that include ground beef and pork.[19] According to the US, the statistics are not very accurate and miss some amounts which
have been included in the 2013 Final Rule. However, even using the figures
provided by the US, there are still over 50% percent of the beef supply that
are not covered by the COOL measure. China is of the view that, although necessary
exemption could be allowed in order to reflect the complexity of economy,
significant percentage of exemption would likely show that the objective of a
technical regulation is arbitrary and not even-handed. And what is important is
that the exemption has been found by the Appellate Body to constitute a very
important element demonstrating that the legal disctiction is arbitrary and not
even-handed, but it remains in the place.
9. China notes the US
repeatedly argued in the second submission that the design and operation of the
three exemptions does not have any nexus to any detrimental impact and the
exemptions themselves are perfectly even-handed.
10. However, China is not
persuaded by the US's argument. The asymmetry between the coverage of the Amended
COOL Measure and the burdens it imposes on all imports was an important
evidence for the Appellate Body to conclude that the COOL Measure is not
even-handed. The US tends to argue that only those exemptions that directly
discriminate the imported products need to be revised in the implementation
stage. But the Appellate Body has made it clear: "In assessing
even-handedness, a panel must ‘carefully scrutinize the particular
circumstances of the case, that is, the design, architecture, revealing
structure, operation, and application of the technical regulation at issue'."
In this regard, we agree with Canada that those exemptions are elements of the
original COOL measure, and form part of the measure's "overall
architecture" that the Appellate Body considered in its analysis.
Therefore, China is of the view that, without taking any measure to change the
scope and remove or minimize the exemptions of the COOL measure, it will be
very difficult to imagine how the Amended COOL Measure may cure the inconsistency
found by the Panel and Appellate Body in particular.
2. Whether
the Amended COOL measure is consistent with Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement
- Whether
the "two-step necessity" test
under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement alleged by Mexico is correct
11. In its first written submission,
Mexico submits in its explanation of Article 2.2
that the Appellate Body effectively established a two-step test to determine
whether a measure is more trade-restrictive than necessary. According to
Mexico, "The first step starts with the statement ‘[a] panel should begin
by considering factors that include'" [20]: "(i) the degree of contribution made by the measure to the
legitimate objective at issue; (ii) the trade-restrictiveness of the measure;
and (iii) the nature of the risks at issue and the gravity of consequences that
would arise from non-fulfilment of the objective(s) pursued by the Member
through the measure".[21] According to Mexico, the first step "requires a weighing and
balancing of relevant factors in respect of the challenged measure itself"[22]. And according to Mexcio, there is also a second step, which "starts
with the statement ‘[i]n most cases, a comparison of the challenged measure and
possible alternative measures should be undertaken'".[23] According to Mexico, this step "involves a weighing and balancing
analysis similar to that under the first step, except that it is undertaken in
respect of a comparison between the challenged measure and each reasonably
available less trade-restrictive alternative measure."[24]
12. Mexico also submits that "when weighed and balanced in a
holistic manner, it is clear from these factors that the trade-restrictiveness
of the Amended COOL Measure is disproportionate to the risks that
non-fulfilment would create."[25] Mexico believes "the fact that the Amended COOL Measure might make some contribution to
the objective does not outweigh the other relevant factors."[26] Accordingly, Mexico
thinks "the trade-restrictiveness of the Amended COOL Measure is
unnecessary and it is inconsistent with Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement."[27]
13. China is of the view that the comparison
of the challenged measure and possible alternative measures is a integrated
part of analysis of whether the technical regulation is more trade restrictive
than necessary to fulfill its legitimate objective instead of a standalone
analysis due to the following reasons.
14. Firstly, the phrase "comparison
of the challenged measure and possible alternative measures" is not the
language appearing in the text of Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement,
instead, it is developed by the Panel and Appellate Body in the interpretation
of the second sentence of Article 2.2. Therefore, it can only be part of
the test instead of an addition to the interpretation of the second sentence.
15. Secondly, the
language of Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement suggests that the
technical regulations have inherent characteristics of trade restrictiveness.
Therefore, what is important is not whether the trade restiveness of a measure
is necessary, but whether it exceeds the extent to fulfil a legitimate
objective. Without weighting the factors contributing to the legitimate
objective and trade-restiveness, it will be hard to come to the conclusion. In
most cases, it could be very difficult to quantify the extent of contribution
to the legitimate objective and trade-restiveness, and therefore, it is useful
to examine the availability of alternative measures.
16. Thirdly, the Panel
report on EC-Seal Products also confirms that the Mexico' interpretation is not
appropriate. The Panel states "an examination of the obligations under Article 2.2
requires a relational analysis of all of the following elements: (a)
trade-restrictiveness of the EU Seal Regime; (b) degree of the measure's
contribution to the identified objective; and (c) availability of alternative measures."[28] Therefore, the
discussion on alternative measure should be part of analysis if a measure is more
trade restrictive than necessary to fulfil a legitimate objective.
17. China notes that
Mexico has retreated from its previous position in its second written
submission, and Mexico stated "even if the Panel decides that the Amended
COOL Measure is inconsistent with Article 2.2 on the basis of the
relational weighing and balancing test discussed above, it should make a
comparative analysis of challenged measure and each alternative measure to
ensure that the record is complete in the event of a review by the Appellate
Body". Therefore, China is of the view that the discussion on alternative
measure should be part of analysis if a measure is more trade restrictive than
necessary to fulfill a legitimate objective and that "there are not two
steps, but one." And the "two-step" approach indeed has risk of
lessening the burden of proof and loosening the conditions under Article 2.2.
18. To sum up, China
believes that the unchanged significant exemptions under the Amended COOL
Measure sheds lights on the analysis of consistency of the measure with Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement, and that the "two-step necessity" test is
not a correct approach for Article 2.2 test.
ANNEX
C-3
integrated
executive summary of colombia
I. INTRODUCTION
1. Colombia, as a Member of the WTO, had a
systemic interest in the application of Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
In its intervention Colombia wanted to reiterate what was expressed in previous
opportunities during the present dispute, in the sense that an appropriate
interpretation of this provision is essential to avoid unnecessary barriers to
trade.
II. INTERPRETATION OF ARTICLE 2.2 OF THE TBT
2. First, Colombia considered important to
highlight that the debate in the present issue was not whether the objective
pursued by the amended COOL measure was legitimate or not. In fact, previous
Panels and the Appellate Body have found that consumer's information is a
legitimate objective under Article 2 of the TBT Agreement[29]. Colombia's submission
related to the standard that the Panel must apply in order to determine if the
adopted measure is in accordance with Article 2.2 of the TBT. As Colombia
stated in its submission, Article 2.2 "more restrictive than
necessary" standard might imply either a complex or a simple approach to
the standard on necessity.
3. Colombia
considered that the construction of a proper standard for assessing whether
a technical regulation "is more trade-restrictive than necessary to
achieve the contribution it makes to the legitimate objective", seems
extremely relevant in the process of designing, adopting and assessing a TBT
measure. Therefore, Colombia respectfully suggested the Panel in this case to
take into account the fold arguments in order to clarify the "more
trade-restrictive than necessary" standard of article 2.2 of the TBT.
4. However, in Colombia's opinion a Member
could also proceed in a simpler way, proving necessity by showing that a trade
restrictive measure, as such, was either a proportional or a proper response to
achieve a legitimate policy objective. Thus, in this vein, the definition of
proportional also means that a measure corresponds, matches or is equivalent in
size or amount to something else; in this case, to achieve a legitimate
objective.[30] According to Colombia,
it is a matter of reasonability used by several courts around the World, and by
the WTO legal texts.[31] In the end, the fact
that a measure is proportional to achieve a legitimate objective means that
such a measure is reasonable, and not more trade restrictive than necessary to
achieve such a legitimate objective.
5. In other words, rather than demanding a
unique assessment involving, among other elements, the pondering of a measure's
"degree of contribution of the TBT to the legitimate objective",
article 2.2 allows Members to construe the "more trade restrictive than
necessary" standard under two scopes: a complex approach or a more simple
one, that allow to analyze whether the measure was, at the moment of its
adoption, either an appropriate, a proportional or a reasonable policy response
to achieve a legitimate objective.
6. As it has been pointed out by some authors,
"proportionality is a trade-off-device which helps resolve conflicts
between different norms, principles, and values. It is also a determining
factor for the role of courts in reviewing administrative or legislative
measures. Proportionality thus provides a legal standard against which
individual or state measures can be reviewed. From a more procedural
perspective, proportionality is closely related to the issues of intensity of
review-the level of scrutiny exercised by judges-and whether there should be a
full review on the merits or a more deferential standard of judicial review."[32]
III. THE
PANEL'S OBJECTIVE ASSESSMENT PERSUANT TO ARTICLE 21.5
7. Colombia recalled the Appellate Body's
previous statements when it acknowledged, "that Members enjoy the right to
determine the legitimate policies they want to pursue".[33] Therefore "WTO
Members have a large measure of autonomy to determine their own policies (…).
Colombia highlighted that so far as it concerns the WTO, that autonomy is
circumscribed only by the need to respect the requirements of the General
Agreement and the other covered agreements."[34]
8. It was Colombia's position, that the Panel
and the Appellate Body should show some kind of comity when assessing a Member's
public policy, and its trade restrictiveness. This applies for a technical
regulation, and the "more trade-restrictive than necessary" standard "to
achieve the contribution it makes to the legitimate objective".
Additionally, this "degree of contribution" standard seems to be more
like an ex-post review based not in the data or information available at the
moment that the measure was issued, but with the information available at the
date of its review. Hence, in Colombia's opinion that is not the appropriate
comity that both, Panels and the Appellate Body, should show to a Member's
policy under the DSU.
9. According to the Black's Law Dictionary,
comity stands for "courtesy; complaisance; respect; a willingness to grant
a privilege, not as a matter of right, but out of deference and good will".
It was Colombia's opinion that the WTO provides Members with leeway to adopt
technical measures in order to achieve an objective. Colombia was referring to
this meaning of comity. There must be a balance in the Panel's analysis between
the regulatory objective of a measure and the conformity of such measure to WTO
provisions. The purpose of Article 2.2 of the TBT is to allow a Member
certain discretion with regard to its regulatory powers, always bearing in mind
that these regulatory powers cannot amount to be unnecessary barriers to trade.
10. Pursuant to Article 11 of the DSU the
Panel has to conduct an objective assessment of the facts of the case, of the
adopted measure, and of the relevant provisions under the Covered Agreements.
When considering the facts of the case the Panel does not have to do a de novo
examination, a complete repetition of the Member's fact finding, nor it has to
have total deference towards the Member's fact submission. The Panel, complying
with the mandate of standard review encompassed in Article 11 has to
analyse all the relevant facts in order to determine if the adopted measure is
in compliance with the obligations under the WTO.
11. Bearing this in mind, Colombia considered
that a Panel is not allowed to conduct an ex-post review of the adopted measure
in every case. This would be contrary, not only to the comity that the Panel
should show to the Member's regulatory powers, but also to Article 3.2 of
the DSU in as much as it would not provide the system with security and
predictability. If the Panel were to conduct its review of the facts with an
ex-post perspective, depending on the factual context at the time of the
decision, then every measure adopted by a Member would be subject to a
continuous scrutiny by the DSB, depriving the system of security and
predictability.
12. Therefore, in Colombia's opinion a Panel
should keep a delicate balance when assessing a measure. In principle and based
in articles 11 and 3.2 of the DSU, a Panel should start considering the factual
elements that an authority of a Member had available when it was assessing the
chance of imposing a particular measure. Then, according to Colombia, a Panel
should assess the effects of a measure as such; and just in case this
information is not enough in order to conduct an objective assessment, a Panel
may start examining criteria or factual findings that came after the measure
was discussed at the DSB on an ex post basis.
13. Colombia considered that this case rose
important questions on the interpretation and application of Article 2.2
of the TBT. While not taking a final position on the merits of the case,
Colombia requested the Panel to carefully review the scope of the claims in
light of the observations made throughout this submission.
ANNEX C-4
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of the european union
1. Third
party rights. Since the Panel modified the standard working
procedures in Appendix 3 DSU to permit the shifting of fact, evidence and
argument to the second phase, it must adopt re-balancing measures preserving
(not enhancing) third party rights, as mandated in Article 10 DSU, which
the Panel must not diminish. The Panel does not require the parties' agreement.
This is required by the multilateral nature of dispute settlement and the
principles of due process and consent. It is particularly important in
balancing cases, such as the present one; and where a defence has a significant
role to play. It is particularly appropriate in the case of a public hearing.
Thus, third parties must have the right to: be present throughout the hearing;
comment at the invitation of the Panel; receive the questions and responses
thereto; and respond to written questions.
2. Relationship
between original and compliance proceedings. There is no formal
rule of precedent in WTO law, although original proceedings and compliance
proceedings are part of a continuous process, and compliance panels are
expected to be guided by their prior findings. There is also no rule of res judicata, although compliance panels may refer to prior
findings as part of their objective assessment.
3. Scope of
these compliance proceedings. The amended COOL measure is a
declared measure taken to comply within the scope of these compliance
proceedings. It can only meaningfully and reasonably be considered as a whole.
The facts of EC – Bed Linen (Article 21.5 – India)
were different and the reasoning in that case does not apply.
4. Order of
analysis. The Panel should begin with the more specific
agreement: the TBT Agreement. It should follow the order of analysis in
the original proceedings: Article 2.1 then Article 2.2.
5. Article IX
GATT and Agreement on Rules of Origin. The Panel should not make
any findings regarding Article IX GATT or the Agreement on Rules of
Origin, which are not before it, and should ensure that nothing in its report
prejudges the interpretation or application of those provisions in another
case.
6. Article 2.1
TBT. Several provisions of the covered agreements seek a balance
between a desire to avoid unnecessary obstacles to international trade and a
recognition of a Member's right to regulate in an even-handed
manner in pursuit of a legitimate objective. The second TBT recital confirms
that the GATT and TBT overlap in scope and have similar objectives; that the
TBT expands on pre-existing GATT disciplines; and that the two should be
interpreted in a coherent and consistent manner. The national treatment
obligations of Articles III:4 and 2.1 are built around the same core
terms. The balance set out in the TBT preamble, and in particular in the fifth
and sixth recitals, is not in principle different from the balance set out in
the GATT, where the national treatment obligation in Article III:4 is
qualified by the general exceptions provision of Article XX. The fifth and
sixth recitals are reflected, inter alia, in Article 2.1
TBT. Article 2.2 also informs contextually Article 2.1. Thus, in
cases involving an alleged de facto
breach, that same balance is to be found in Article 2.1 TBT itself.
7. Determining the scope of
the imported product and the scope of the
domestic product to be compared is about the
nature and extent of any competitive relationship
between the two things being considered as potentially part of the product. Any distortive effects that the measure itself
might have are to be discounted. Regulatory distinctions are only relevant to
the extent that they find expression in the relevant competitive relationship,
such as through consumer preferences. Once the imported and domestic products have
been properly identified, Article 2.1 TBT requires a panel to compare the
treatment accorded under the technical regulation to all like
products imported from the complaining Member (that is, the "group" or
"universe" of imported products) with that accorded to all like domestic products (that is, the "group"
or "universe" of domestic like products). There must be a genuine relationship between the measure and an adverse
impact on competitive opportunities for imported products – conditions
resulting solely from private actions cannot
ground a breach. Measures that create incentives may breach. Asymmetrical
impact resulting from the lower market share of imports is an exacerbating
element, but is not sufficient. However, the national treatment obligation of Article 2.1
does not require Members to accord no less favourable treatment to each and
every imported product as compared to each and every domestic like product.
Regulatory distinctions that stem exclusively
from the pursuit of legitimate objectives are permissible.
8. In assessing whether or not
there is less favourable treatment the existence of a detrimental impact on competitive opportunities for the group of
imported vis-à-vis the group of domestic like products is relevant but not dispositive. A panel must further analyze whether the
detrimental impact on imports stems exclusively
from a legitimate regulatory distinction rather
than reflecting discrimination. In making this determination, a panel must
carefully scrutinize the particular circumstances
of the case, that is, the design, architecture, revealing structure, operation
and application of the measure, and in particular whether that measure is even-handed. There are no facts that are per se excluded, it being for the litigant asserting such
facts to persuade the adjudicator of their relevance. The burden of proof rests
in principle with the party asserting the affirmative.
9. In this case, in assessing
whether or not there is a detrimental impact, the relevant comparison is
between the situation before adoption of the original COOL measure and the
present situation. All regulatory change may involve costs that, in the short
term, will inevitably be unequally distributed amongst existing firms and
Members as a function of their past investment decisions. This does not mean
the measure breaches. What is important is that, in the long term, all firms
and Members can adjust to the new regulatory regime and enjoy equal competitive
opportunities. The mere fact that unit regulatory compliance costs may be
higher for firms or Members with lower production volumes or market share does
not establish breach. Firms and Members make their own choices about economies
of scale. Propensity to breach WTO law is not a function of the relative size
of Members or their firms or their production volumes or market shares. A
measure that regulates a downstream product that has effects on upstream
products, or vice versa, justifies an
assessment that encompasses all such aspects.
10. The root of the problem in
this case is that the production chain currently employed by Canadian and
Mexican firms is partly transnational,
which, as a matter of fact, necessitates more specific record keeping,
segregation, and therefore higher costs. In this respect, it is helpful to consider
the situation in which birth, raising and slaughter occur only in one Member.
Does this scenario, which does not involve any transnational element in the
production or processing chain, reveal de facto
discrimination? It is very difficult to see any. Furthermore, it is very
difficult to see that, in this scenario, the exemptions for restaurants, small
retailers and ground meat would alter that conclusion. It is also helpful to
think about the case from the perspective of the MFN principle. If the transnational
element is determinative in concluding that there is a de facto
breach of the national treatment obligation, what would this imply with respect
to possible de facto breaches of the MFN rule?
Would it not mean that, if there are two third countries, one of which
maintains the chain of production or processing entirely within its own
territory, and the second of which does not – but rather carries out some part
of it in a further third country – there would also be a breach of the MFN
rule? This seems to imply that a regulating Member might find it impossible to regulate because, whatever origin neutral rule
is put in place, there would be de facto
discrimination.
11. Article 2.2
TBT Agreement. The legitimate objective
of the measure is to provide consumers with information about origin and
points-of-production. There may be many reasons why consumers might want such
information. Some consumers might want to boost trade or development. Some
might have their own opinions about issues they perceive to be associated with
a particular product or production process and wish to express them when making
choices about what they consume. There is always a concern that such labels may
facilitate irrational origin-based discrimination. In an increasingly integrated
global economy it may become increasingly difficult to discern a rational link
between origin described in terms of a particular WTO Member and a particular
issue. Nevertheless, the objective is legitimate. Once origin labelling is
accepted as a legitimate objective, that same approach has to be adopted for
all WTO Members, and it is problematic to go on to question the motives of
particular consumers. In a very real sense they are
the market. Even if some irrational origin-based discrimination persists or
re-emerges, it is simply part of the task of firms to overcome it through
information and marketing. The same reasoning generally applies, by extension,
to other types of labels. Food labelling is a particular issue. We are speaking
of what people choose to eat, for themselves and their children. Information
and evidence about what labels consumers want may be relevant to an assessment
under Article 2.2 TBT, but not determinative. WTO Member governments also
have the right to determine what their legitimate regulatory objectives are.
12. The measure is significantly trade-restrictive, such that a consideration
of the other elements of Article 2.2 TBT is necessary. The
trade-restriction must be significant. It
is not possible nor permissible to put a precise number on what this means: it
is something that can only be considered on a case-by-case basis. This is but
one part of a more complex mechanism, so precise quantification may be
unnecessary. But this requirement of significance implies there is a category
of regulations that do not significantly restrict trade and do not therefore
breach Article 2.2 TBT. To be meaningful, this category must be reasonably
populated. Furthermore, this significance requirement, as well the requirement
to compare the trade-restrictiveness of alternative measures, implies some
degree of precision about what the concept of trade-restriction means, and how
it is to be generally calibrated, if not precisely measured.
13. The concept of
trade-restrictiveness encompasses what effects a measure has had, and may have
in the future. However, it may be difficult to
appreciate the degree of trade-restrictiveness on a hypothetical basis.
Modelling may be used, but may be expensive, data may be difficult to obtain,
and the conclusion may be excessively dependent on the assumptions. In a
hypothetical, attempts at precise measurement may be misplaced. At some point
mooted trade-restrictiveness may be too remote to establish breach. Under the TBT Agreement,
regulations may be consistent when adopted but become inconsistent later (and vice versa). Excessively speculative cases can be deferred.
In the short term, all regulatory change can impose one-off costs and so appear
to restrict trade. However, in the long term, once firms adapt, some regulatory
change may increase trade, or at least be fully absorbed by traders. Thus, one
should not be too quick to jump to the conclusion that a new regulation
restricts trade just because there is an initial shock. A good place to look
for guidance about the meaning of trade-restrictiveness could be arbitration
panel reports. However, one should be cautious about transposing excessively. Article 3.8
of the DSU presumes nullification or impairment; and no special interest is
required to bring a case. In short, assessing trade-restrictiveness should be
grounded in reasonable, balanced and qualitative considerations of good sense,
accessible to all Members.
14. The concept of
trade-restrictiveness involves focussing on the impact of a particular measure
on imports. If a measure has no impact on imports, it cannot be said to be
trade-restrictive. An asymmetrical distribution of costs may be significant,
but rather something to analyse under the heading of whether or not there is a de facto breach of the national treatment obligation in
Article 2.1. Regulation is rarely an easy task, especially in a complex
and more integrated global economy, and often necessitates the striking of
reasonable compromises. Pointing to specific inconsistencies at the margins may
not always reveal much about the overall balance of a particular regulation. It
is legitimate to regulate for some of the people. A US consumer concerned about
such issues can choose. They can go to a large supermarket and read the labels;
and at the same time choose to avoid restaurants, processed foods and small
retailers. This does not make the measure WTO inconsistent. The same is true
with respect to ground meat: the measure simply allows concerned US consumers
to avoid it.
15. With respect to Canada and
Mexico's argument that the measure causes a reduction in the price of their
imported products, they appear to be treating the concepts of trade restriction
and nullification or impairment as being the same thing. We do not think that
this is correct. However, what they appear to be arguing is that if they do
raise their prices (in order to account for their increased costs) then, all
other things being equal, they will lose volume, and that is the required
restriction of trade, albeit an anticipated one rather than an actual one.
Perhaps they are reticent about making this clear because they are concerned
about a counter-argument from the US to the effect that what they would
experience would be caused by their own actions and not by the measure at issue.
They should have no concern. If the measure is a genuine and substantial cause
of the trade restriction, that will be sufficient. There can be more than one
genuine and substantial cause. Thus, a hypothetical price rise would not break
the causal link for the purposes of their claims under Articles 2.1 and
2.2. In effect, Canada and Mexico appear to be mitigating the trade loss (in
terms of volume) that would otherwise accrue to them by reducing their prices
and thus absorbing the additional costs, at least temporarily. Mitigation of
loss is foreseen in Article 39 of the ILC Articles on the
Responsibility of States for Internationally Wrongful Acts, which provides that
account shall be taken of the contribution to the injury by wilful or negligent
action or omission of the injured States. WTO Members mitigating trade loss
should not, for that reason, be precluded from pursuing a claim pursuant to Articles 2.1
or 2.2 TBT.
16. It is not for WTO
adjudicators to rank in general and abstract terms the importance of legitimate
regulatory objectives, which may overlap and which are rarely comparable. In
WTO law, the fixing of the ALOP is strictly reserved to the regulating Member.
It is not for WTO adjudicators to weigh the relative values of different WTO
Members. Different WTO Members have different values, sometimes in counterpoint
to each other. Attempting to harmonise or rank them is no task for a judge; and
it is not a task that has been conferred on WTO adjudicators. Regulatory
competition promotes efficiency and makes a positive contribution to the
objectives of the WTO. Regulatory autonomy is as much a pillar of the WTO as
MFN and national treatment. The WTO has no mandate to apply a pure
proportionality test. If a particular measure is put through the disciplines of
the TBT Agreement, and no breach is found, but a WTO judge simply comes to
a point at which what appears to that judge to be a very large trade
restriction is being justified by what seems to that judge to be a matter of
very small concern, the WTO judge must defer to the national measure. It is not
for WTO judges to value legitimate objectives: that is reserved to WTO Members.
17. Canada and Mexico read Article 2.2
as if it refers to the consequences
that non-fulfilment would create. They have in mind the proposition that the consequence of someone being killed, for
example, is graver than the consequence
of someone eating a steak without having accurate information about the place
of birth, raising and slaughter of the animal from which the steak is derived.
On this basis, they imagine that the alternative measure could make a lesser
contribution to the legitimate objective, because the consequence of
non-fulfilment is, in relative terms, not so serious. However, Article 2.2
does not refer to the consequences of non-fulfilment. It refers to the risks non-fulfilment would create. This
does not imply any diminishing of the ALOP. It merely directs the enquiry
towards the question of whether or not there is a rational relationship between
the various parts of the measure or alternative measure.
18. Although the list in the
final sentence of Article 2.2 is open, the three listed items are all technical in nature: none of them empower
a panel to question the ALOP. If
this provision would be calling upon panels to provide a general ranking of the
relative political values of WTO Members, then
one would expect other kinds of references, such
as, for example, to the UN Charter or other international agreements. These are
referenced in many other provisions, but not here. In short, a panel has full
authority to consider whether or not the relationships between the various
moving parts of the measure or alternative measure are rational, and this is
the additional element of weighing and balancing – not a re-setting of the
ALOP.
19. In the context of Article 2.2
TBT, there is no direct relationship between the degree of asymmetry in the
distribution of regulatory costs between domestic and foreign firms and the
legitimacy of a particular regulatory distinction or objective. That is because
(1) Article 2.2 is about necessity (not discrimination) and (2) as a
matter of logic, there is no necessary connection between the two concepts.
Thus, regulatory costs could be distributed in a perfectly equal way both in the
short and long term; but the regulatory distinction or objective might
nevertheless not be legitimate. If the measure significantly restricts trade
(constituting an unnecessary obstacle to international trade) and the
regulatory distinction or objective is not legitimate, Article 2.2 will be
breached. Conversely, regulatory costs could be distributed in a perfectly
unequal way both in the short term and in the long term; but the regulatory
distinction or objective might nevertheless be legitimate. Although the TBT Agreement
classically applies to regulations of general application to all WTO Members,
its application is not precluded in the case of measures relating to goods
originating from a particular WTO Member. Just as under the SPS Agreement, in
some instances this might be justified or even necessary. The unequal
distribution is something that may be taken into account in the overall
assessment, but it does not necessarily result in a re-opening of the question
of whether or not the objective is legitimate.
20. Similarly, in the context of
Article 2.1 TBT, there is no direct relationship between the degree of
asymmetry in the distribution of regulatory costs between domestic and foreign
firms and the legitimacy of a particular regulatory distinction or objective,
because, as a matter of logic, there is no necessary connection between the two
concepts. In the context of a de facto
breach of the national treatment obligation there must be a negative impact on
competitive conditions or opportunities for foreign products, at least in the
short term. What constitutes the short term is something to be considered on a
case-by-case basis. In this particular case, to the extent that the
alternatives (the importing Members conduct all operations on their own territories
or establish their own slaughterhouses in the US) may not be reasonably
available, there would appear to be a long term impact on market structures
that constitutes a disincentive to the market integration pursued by the WTO
Agreement.
21. The mechanism by which the
volume of imports are reduced or suppressed compared to domestic sales volume,
on an actual or anticipated basis, classically involves an asymmetrical
incidence of costs. That is because, as their costs increase, and importing
firms raise prices relative to domestic producers, in order to remain
profitable, all other things being equal, they will lose volume. Nevertheless,
as in the case of Article 2.2, this does not necessarily mean that the
regulatory distinction or objective is not legitimate. Conversely, if there is
no asymmetry in the distribution of regulatory costs in the short or long term
then it is difficult to see in what sense there may be a negative impact on
competitive conditions or opportunities for foreign products. In such a case,
there is no breach of Article 2.1, irrespective of the regulatory
distinction or objective being pursued.
22. The differences between
claims of de facto breach of Article 2.1
and breach of Article 2.2 are that (1) Article 2.1 focusses on discrimination
whilst Article 2.2 focusses on necessity (2) Article 2.1 requires a
particular impact on the competitive conditions or opportunities for imports
whilst Article 2.2 requires only a significant restriction of trade and
(3) a particular issue may appear as a fact in the Article 2.1 analysis
(thus just one fact to be taken into account with all the other facts) but as
part of the operation of a particular legal rule in the Article 2.2
analysis (for example, if a measure that significantly restricts trade makes no
contribution to its objective then Article 2.2 is breached – but this
would be only one fact to consider with other facts in the context of Article 2.1).
23. The first
alternative would involve a particular origin rule: substantial transformation. This is
problematic. As the EU has explained above, the Agreement on Rules of Origin
leaves this matter open and to the discretion of WTO Members. If this would be
the only alternative, then, by a process of elimination, the US would
eventually be compelled to adopt it in order to comply. The EU considers that
the TBT Agreement, which does not even refer expressly to origin, was not
adopted in order to effectively compel WTO Members to do something that is
expressly reserved as a matter for their discretion, pursuant to the terms of
the Agreement on Rules of Origin.
24. The second
alternative would certainly be less restrictive of trade.
Slaughterhouses could, in effect, label all meat as originating in Canada and
the US, as long as they had both types of animal within their inventory in the
last 60 days. However, it seems equally clear that this measure would make a
lesser contribution to the objective. For this reason, the EU considers that
the second alternative measure is insufficient for the purposes of establishing
a breach of Article 2.2 TBT.
25. The third
alternative would remove the asymmetry complained of by Canada and
Mexico, would be more trade-restrictive in the sense that it would increase
costs for imports. If it would be the only viable alternative, that would seem
to imply that the only way that the US could comply would be by adopting a
heavier regulatory burden. The EU considers that it is not the task of the WTO
to impose such regulatory decisions on WTO Members. In our view, by definition,
the alternative measure should be one that imposes equivalent or fewer costs.
In so far as Canada and Mexico are concerned about asymmetry, that mater can be
addressed under Article 2.1. Thus, the third alternative measure is
insufficient for the purposes of establishing a breach of Article 2.2 TBT.
26. Article III:4
GATT. The scope and content of Article III:4 of the GATT and the scope of Article 2.1
TBT differ. However, the basic concept of a de facto
breach of a national treatment obligation is the same whether one is in Article III:4
of the GATT or Article 2.1 TBT. It includes a consideration of not only
the impact of the measure on competitive opportunities for imports, but also a
consideration of whether the origin neutral objective or regulatory distinction
is legitimate and even-handed, rather than de facto
discriminatory. If one is going to accept the concept of a de facto
breach, then the necessary quid pro quo is
that one at least considers the reasons for the origin neutral regulatory distinction.
ANNEX
C-5
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of india*
1. India thanks the Panel for this
opportunity to present its views in the present proceedings. India has systemic
interest with respect to certain issues raised in this Article 21.5
proceeding. India does not take any position on the factual aspects of this
dispute but limits its statement only on the issue of the scope of Article 21.5
proceedings.
2. In the present proceeding, the United States
has argued that the scope of a Panel request in an Article 21.5 proceeding
is only limited to the measures which has been taken to comply with the ruling
and recommendations of the DSB and has contended that:
a. GATT Article XXIII: 1(b) claim is
outside the Panel's terms of reference as Article 21.5 proceeding is
limited to the issue of determining the existence of a measure taken to comply
or the consistency with a covered agreement of a measure taken to comply
whereas the claim under GATT Article XXIII:1(b) involves a situation other
than the question of consistency of a measure with a covered agreement.
b. The claim with respect to trace back
and labeling rule for ground beef is outside the terms of reference as these
two measures were not found to be inconsistent. Thus Article 21.5
proceeding cannot be used to raise claims related to an unchanged aspect of the
original measure.
c. Lastly the United States has also
argued that the complainants in the 21.5 proceedings are asserting claims with
respect to issues already considered in the original proceedings. This as per
the United States is contrary to DSU which does not allow the complaining
parties to use compliance proceedings to re raise claims and arguments which
were rejected during the original proceedings.
3. Mr. Chairman, Article 21.5
proceedings are initiated for the purpose of assessing whether the respondent
country has complied with the ruling and recommendation of the DSB. However
while making this assessment, India believes that Article 21.5 proceedings
should
not be limited to evaluating the implementing measure only but instead should
be extended to a full consideration of the factual and legal background against
which the implementing measure is taken.[35]This broad approach would ensure that a
respondent country would not be able to circumvent the ruling and
recommendation of the DSB by complying with the same through one measure,
while, at the same time, negating compliance through another.[36]
4. This position of India is consistent
with the Appellate Body report in Canada — Aircraft (Article 21.5
— Brazil)[37] wherein it concluded
that a review by the Panel pursuant to Article 21.5 of the DSU would not
be limited to examining the measures ‘taken to comply'. Further the Appellate
Body in US Shrimp (21.5) observed that "when the issue concerns the consistency of a new measure
"taken to comply", the task of a panel in a matter referred to it by
the DSB for an Article 21.5 proceeding is to consider that new measure in
its totality. The fulfilment of this task requires that a panel consider both
the measure itself and the measure's application"[38]. Therefore India believes that the scope of a Panel request in an Article 21.5
proceeding includes not only the measure which has been taken to comply with
the ruling and recommendation of the DSB but also its application.
5. India therefore submits that pursuant
to Article 11 of the DSU, the Panel in an Article 21.5 proceeding is
obligated to objectively assess not only whether the respondent party has
complied with the recommendation of the DSB but also evaluate the new measure[39], if any, taken by the
respondent in its entirety. This position of India is consistent with the
objective behind Article 21.5 proceeding as highlighted by the Appellate
Body in US — Softwood
Lumber IV (Article 21.5).[40]
6. India would now address the issue of Article XXIII:1(b)
of GATT and its inclusion in an Article 21.5 proceedings. The Appellate
Body observed in US-Shrimp that a Panel in an Article 21.5 proceeding is required to
consider both the measure itself and measure's application.[41] Therefore if the
application of the new measure implemented pursuant to the ruling and
recommendation of the DSB leads to nullification or impairment as provided
under Article XXIII:1(b) of GATT, India believes that the same can be
pursued by the Panel in this Article 21.5 proceeding. This position of
India is also supported by the Appellate Body report in EC- Asbestos[42] where it observed that Article XXIII:1(b) of GATT sets forth a separate cause of action
for a claim that through the application of a measure, a member has
nullified or impaired benefits accruing to another member, whether or not that
measure conflicts with the provision of GATT 1994. However
whether the application of the new implemented measure leads to nullification
or impairment is a factual exercise which has to be undertaken by the Panel.
7. With respect to the issue concerning
inclusion of trace back and labeling rule for ground beef within the Panel's
terms of reference, Mexico has responded and argued that the complainant is not
challenging the rule with respect to ground beef and
the rule with respect to trace back but are using the same as an argument to
compare with the amended rule for muscle cut of beef and to establish that the
amended COOL measure is a disguised restriction on the international trade
respectively.
8. In this respect, India believes that as
long as the complainants in the present proceeding are not challenging the
aspect of the original measure which was not found to be inconsistent but are
simply using the same as an argument to establish their claim, the same should
be within the Panel's terms of reference.
9. With respect to the issue of re raising
claims in 21.5 proceedings which were rejected in the original proceedings,
India would draw the attention of the Panel that the United States is
ambiguous in its argument as it has not explicitly identified all such claims.
10. India would therefore respectfully
request the Panel to identify the claims which has been re raised by the
complainants in the present proceedings but which were rejected by the Panel in
the original proceedings. If the same relates to the claims of the complainants
under Articles III:4 and XXIII:1(b)
of the GATT 1994 which the original Panel did not address on account of
judicial economy, India believes that the same can be addressed in a Article 21.5
proceeding.
11. This position of India is supported by the
Appellate Body ruling in EC-Bed Linen (21.5)[43] wherein it was observed that in a situation where a panel, in declining to rule on a certain
claim, has provided only a partial resolution of the matter at issue, a
complainant should not be held responsible for the panel's false exercise of
judicial economy, such that a complainant would not be prevented from raising
the claim in a subsequent proceeding.
Therefore India respectfully requests the
Panel to take into consideration the above jurisprudence as outlined above
while assessing the issue of judicial economy, assuming that this was the issue
the United States was referring to with respect to the issue of re raising
claims in Article 21.5 proceedings which were rejected in the original
proceedings.
India thanks the Panel for the opportunity to present its views and to
participate in these proceedings.
ANNEX
C-6
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of japan
Third Party Submission
I. Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement
1. Japan wishes to address one
issue relating to Article 2.1, namely, the relevance of the exemptions
under the Amended COOL measure for purposes of assessing whether there is "treatment
no less favourable."
2. Canada and Mexico explain
that the Amended COOL measure made two key changes to the original
measure: (i) the Amended COOL measure
requires that retail labels for muscle cut covered commodities list the country
or countries in which the animal from which the muscle cut was derived was
born, raised, and slaughtered; and, (ii) it eliminated the commingling
flexibility, i.e., the allowance to use the
mixed origin label on muscle cuts produced the same production day.[44]
3. It would appear that the first change is intended to address part of
the disconnect that the Appellate Body found between the "large amount of
information … tracked and transmitted by upstream producers for purposes of
providing consumers with information on origin" and the "small amount
of this information … actually communicated to consumers in an understandable
manner, if it is communicated at all."[45] However, Japan notes that the Appellate Body
also found it difficult to reconcile that – one the one hand – information
regarding the origin of all livestock had to be identified, tracked, and
transmitted through the chain of production by upstream producers, while – on
the other hand – a considerable proportion of the beef and pork derived from
that livestock would ultimately be exempt from the COOL requirements, and
therefore carry no COOL label at all.[46] Canada and Mexico
underscore the fact that these exemptions remain unchanged.[47]
4. Japan submits that the
Amended COOL measure's exemptions are relevant to the analysis of "treatment
no less favourable" under Article 2.1, even though they are not, on
their own, dispositive of the question of whether the Amended COOL measure is "even-handed".
The exemptions may undermine the proposition that the detrimental impact caused
by the recordkeeping and verification requirements of the Amended COOL measure
stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction because the
exemptions exclude "a considerable portion"[48] of meat products from
the need to provide origin information to consumers. Japan encourages the Panel
to carefully scrutinize the rationale of the exemptions provided under the
Amended COOL measure in light of, among others, the measure's objective of
providing origin information to consumers, and to determine whether the
exemptions are consistent with the requirement that any detrimental impact stem
exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction.
5. In the original
proceedings, the United States maintained that WTO Members should be
allowed to weigh costs and benefits in the design of their technical
regulations, and explained that the United States had decided to adopt
certain exemptions and flexibilities to reduce the costs of compliance for
industry, taking into account the views of interested parties.[49] Japan accepts that when a government designs a technical
regulation, it is reasonable for that government to try to reduce the
compliance costs for market participants by allowing for reasonable exemptions
and flexibilities. This is a consideration that a government can take into
account, along with other relevant factors such as the diminished level of
fulfillment of the objective pursued as a result of the exemptions and
flexibilities, as well as consumer preferences. However, in Japan's view, if a technical regulation modifies the conditions
of competition in the market to the detriment of imported livestock, the
government adopting it would be required to take into account the burdens of
compliance to be borne by imported products as well as those by domestic
products in adopting the technical regulation, including exemptions of the kind
maintained in the Amended COOL measure.
6. Japan observes that the
Amended COOL measure does not seem to address the disproportionate burdens of
compliance that fall on the imported products. Moreover, although the United States indicated in the original proceedings that
the flexibility regarding the use of labels B and C had been added in response
to requests from Canada and its producer groups,[50] this flexibility has been abolished in the Amended COOL measure.
This Panel appears to be
confronted with a
technical regulation that further increases the costs of compliance, thus exacerbating a situation in which
compliance costs were already borne disproportionately by the imported product. The Panel must "carefully
scrutinize the particular circumstances of the case, that is, the design,
architecture, revealing structure, operation, and application of the technical
regulation at issue."[51]
II. Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement
7. In its Article 2.2
arguments, Mexico argues that, in these compliance proceedings, a comparison
with reasonably available alternative measures is not required given the
circumstances of the Amended COOL measure.[52] Mexico finds support
for its view in the Appellate Body Report in US – Tuna II
(Mexico).[53]
8. Japan notes that the two
instances mentioned by the Appellate Body in US – Tuna II
(Mexico) are extreme scenarios where the challenged measure is
either not trade restrictive or makes no contribution at all to achieving the
relevant legitimate objective. Japan further observes that, in the original
proceedings, the Appellate Body recognized that the Panel's findings, and
undisputed facts on the record, indicated that the labeling requirements under
the COOL measure did make some contribution to the objective of providing
consumer information on origin.[54] In the absence of
evidence demonstrating that such contribution has been eliminated completely
under the Amended COOL measure, an assessment of Article 2.2 should
include a comparison of the Amended COOL measure and possible alternative
measures.
9. Canada argues that a
reasonably available alternative measure need not achieve "precisely the
same degree of contribution to the achievement of the objective as that of the
challenged measure in all cases."[55] Mexico makes a similar
point.[56]
10. Japan recalls the Appellate
Body's statement that "the importance of a panel identifying with sufficient
clarity and consistency the objective or objectives pursued by a Member through
a technical regulation cannot be overemphasized."[57] Japan agrees with this
statement, and further observes that the greater the precision with which a
panel identifies the objective pursued by a government, the more accurately the
panel can identify what would constitute an equivalent contribution by a
reasonably available alternative measure. If the objective is not defined with
sufficient precision, the panel may have difficulties deciding whether an
alternative measure can fulfill the objective at a level that is acceptable to
the government adopting the technical regulation.
11. In addition, Japan notes
that the Appellate Body has said, in the context of evaluating "necessity"
under Article XX of the GATT 1994 and Article XIV of the GATS,
that a measure qualifies as an alternative measure if it preserves for the
responding Member the right to achieve its desired level of protection with
respect to objective pursued.[58] The Appellate Body's
interpretation of the necessity test in these similar contexts would seem to
require a stricter comparison than is suggested by Canada and Mexico, between
the degree of contribution achieved by the challenged measure and the degree
achieved by any alternatives raised by a complaining party.
12. Mexico finds support for the
more flexible comparison that it advocates in the language in Article 2.2,
calling for consideration of "the risks non-fulfilment would create."
The Appellate Body, however, has explained that "the risks non-fulfilment
would create" is a "further element of weighing and balancing"
in the analysis under Article 2.2.[59] In other words, "the
risks non-fulfilment would create" is a factor, among others, to be
considered in weighing and balancing under Article 2.2 and does not
provide a basis for a more flexible comparison between the challenged measure
and any reasonably available alternatives. Therefore, a lesser degree of
contribution by the alternative measure cannot be justified in the light of the
risks non-fulfilment would create, as Mexico contends.
Third Party Oral Statement
I. "Legitimate
Regulatory Distinction" Test under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
1. With respect to Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement, the United States does not appear to contest
that the Amended COOL measure has a detrimental impact on the imported
products. Instead, the contestation centers on the second prong of the test
articulated by the Appellate Body previously,[60] that is, whether the detrimental
impact stems from a legitimate regulatory distinction. In the earlier TBT
disputes, the Appellate Body initially referred to this test as involving an
inquiry about even-handedness. In a subsequent case, the Appellate Body
referred to the measure being "designed or applied in a manner that
constitutes a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination" as an
example of a situation that would not be considered to be even-handed.[61] Japan further notes
that, in applying the even-handedness test, the Appellate Body has also focused
on the "calibration" of a measure as well as the proportionality of
certain requirements. Japan recalls that "even-handedness" is not
treaty text and is, in fact, twice removed from it. The concept is an
elaboration or clarification of the second prong of the test articulated by the
Appellate Body. It is a useful concept and a good illustration of the type of
discrimination that is prohibited by Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement.
However, Japan would caution against relying too rigidly on this term.
2. In Japan's view, the
assessment of whether the detrimental impact stems exclusively from a
legitimate regulatory distinction broadly encompasses consideration of two
elements. The first element relates to the legitimacy of the rationale or
objective that the regulatory distinction pursues. The second element looks
more broadly at the design or manner in which the measure is applied in the
light of the rationale or objective claimed to be pursued. Whether the
examination of these two elements is part of a single, holistic assessment of "even-handedness"
(or legitimacy) or separate inquiries, in our view, both elements must be
properly considered.
3. As regards the first
element, Japan does not understand the Appellate Body to have suggested that Article 2.1
allows all possible regulatory distinctions. Rather, the regulatory
distinctions must further one of the policy objectives recognized in the TBT Agreement.
This should not be a superficial inquiry that is satisfied merely because the
measure has some connection to the objective pursued. A panel must confirm that
the regulatory distinction drawn by the regulation in question can indeed
further the objectives allegedly pursued by it.
4. In this case, the Panel
must scrutinize what information, which is not already provided voluntarily,
the United States considers that consumers need in order to avoid confusion
or deception when shopping. Where certain information would be unnecessary from
a consumer point of view, the disclosure requirement merely imposes additional
costs on the covered products without providing any value or utility. In
addition, the Panel must scrutinize the relationship between the measure and
the objective it pursues. Under the particular facts of this case, this inquiry
must examine the manner in which the information is provided to consumers and
whether the measure in fact provides consumers with the information that they
purportedly require.
5. With respect to the second
element, the Appellate Body has stated that, in assessing even‑handedness, a
panel must "carefully scrutinize the particular circumstances of the case,
that is, the design, architecture, revealing structure, operation, and
application of the technical regulation at issue".[62] We recall that, in this
case, the United States has questioned whether the exemptions are relevant
for the assessment of less favourable treatment. Japan does not see any reason
to exclude ex ante any exemptions from the
assessment of less favourable treatment. To fully understand the scope of a
measure and how it operates, it is often necessary to consider any and all
exemptions.
6. Japan understands that the
particular exemptions at issue exclude certain meat products from the scope of
the Amended COOL measure. In so doing, the exemptions appear to effectively
create an additional product category of origin "unknown" or "unidentified"
under the Amended COOL measure. The existence of this category covering a large
proportion of meat products may cast doubt on the need for the information
required under the four types of labels of the Amended COOL measure because
meat products falling under that additional category do not provide origin
information to consumers. Also, by allowing certain meat products to be put in
the additional category, the exemptions appear to preclude them from being
classified in any of the four categories on the basis of the relevant
regulatory distinction, i.e. the three production steps and the countries in
which such steps take place. Under these circumstances, Japan wonders whether the
regulatory distinction can be said to be calibrated or tailored to the basis or
rationale of the distinction.
7. Therefore, Japan
respectfully requests the Panel to take into account the above considerations to
examine whether the relevant regulatory distinction under the Amended COOL
measure is legitimate or designed or applied in an even-handed manner, so as to
determine whether the detrimental impact on imported livestock stems
exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction.
II. The Relationship Between Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement and Article III:4 of the GATT 1994
8. The parties would appear to
hold different views as to whether the phrase "treatment no less favourable"
should be interpreted in the same manner under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
and Article III:4 of the GATT 1994. Another question raised in these
proceedings is whether the second prong of the de facto
discrimination test that the Appellate Body developed in the context of Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement[63] applies to the
assessment of de facto discrimination
claims under Article III:4 of the GATT 1994.
9. At the outset, Japan
recalls that the non-discrimination rule under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement
applies specifically "in respect of technical regulations". Thus the
application of the second prong of the test developed by the Appellate Body is unique
to technical regulations. In contrast, Article III:4 of the GATT 1994
addresses a broad and diverse range of measures, including technical
regulations. Thus, it would arguably be prudent to exercise a degree of caution
when drawing guidance from the interpretation developed in the context of Article 2.1,
even though we also recognize that Article 2.1 provides context to the interpretation
of Article III:4 "in respect of technical regulations".
10. Japan also notes that the
Appellate Body developed the second prong of the test at least partly based on
the "absence among the provisions of the TBT Agreement of a general
exception provision similar to Article XX of the GATT 1994"[64] and the structural
parallel between the balance set out in the TBT Agreement, on the one
hand, and "the balance set out in the GATT 1994, where obligations
such as national treatment in Article III are qualified by the general
exceptions provision of Article XX."[65] Japan further notes
that Article 2.2 also contains certain elements set out in Article XX
of the GATT 1994. Therefore, although a technical regulation could be
found to be consistent with Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement and yet
inconsistent with Article III:4 of the GATT 1994, under the Appellate
Body's theory, this "inconsistency" could be resolved by the
application of Article XX of the GATT 1994.
11. That being said, it is
theoretically possible that some technical regulations may not find protection
under Article XX. In such a situation, Japan notes that the TBT Agreement
does not contain the same helpful guidance found in Article 2.4 of the SPS
Agreement.
12. To address such interpretive
discrepancies, some Members suggest to import the interpretation of Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement directly to Article III:4 of the GATT 1994,
thus requiring the assessment of a de facto
claim of less favourable treatment under Article III:4 to follow a two-step
analysis similar to the one developed under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement.
This approach has its attraction. After all, both Article III:4 of the GATT 1994
and Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement address "treatment no less
favourable". Moreover, technical regulations in principle are not only
regulated under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement, but also fall among
the types of measures regulated by Article III:4 of the GATT 1994.
13. The approach that Japan has
described, however, is not without difficulties. For one thing, there would
appear to be some tension between this approach and the approach followed by
the Appellate Body in earlier cases. Indeed, this would not be the first time
that consideration of the objectives pursued by the challenged measure is
sought to be introduced into Article III:4, but to date the Appellate Body
apparently has been reluctant to accept such considerations, even though the
Appellate Body has taken such considerations into account when the objectives
have a bearing under one of the criteria of the "like products" analysis,
as was the case in EC – Asbestos.[66] Japan also recalls the
Appellate Body's statement that, with respect to regulatory distinctions based
on a regulatory objective, such "distinctions among products that have
been found to be like are better drawn when considering subsequently, whether
less favourable treatment has been accorded".[67] The other difficulty
stems from Article XX itself. If some flexibility were introduced into Article III:4,
questions arise as to whether this would make Article XX meaningless. These
questions should be answered taking into consideration the fact that certain
restrictions on exports or imports of, for example, exhaustible natural
resources or non-automatic import licensing requirements, which are found to be
inconsistent with GATT Article XI:1 can be justified only under Article XX.
Japan also notes that under the chapeau of Article XX, the issue is whether
"the reasons given for this discrimination bear [] rational connection to
the objective falling within the purview of a paragraph of Article XX, or
would go against that objective", as found by the Appellate Body in Brazil – Retreaded Tyres.[68]
14. The Panel must carefully
address these interpretive difficulties in resolving the issue of the
consistent interpretation of TBT Article 2.1 and GATT Article III:4
(in light of GATT Article XX(b)) for technical regulations raised by the
parties.
III. Article 2.2
of the TBT Agreement
15. Finally, Japan wishes to
address the following two points regarding the analysis under Article 2.2:
(i) the scope of the concept of "trade restrictiveness", and (ii) the
role of "reasonably available alternative measures" in the Article 2.2
analysis.
16. Japan notes that despite the
apparent differences in the way in which the parties define "trade-restrictiveness",
they do not essentially disagree on the factors to examine in the "trade-restrictiveness"
analysis. Canada recalls that WTO jurisprudence interpreted the term "trade-restrictive"
to mean "having a limiting effect on trade" and argues that a measure
that affects the conditions of competition to the detriment of imported
livestock is trade-restrictive.[69] Mexico takes a similar
position. The United States interprets the term "trade restrictive"
as referring to something that has a limiting effect on trade, that is, limits
market access.[70] Although the United States
argues that the term "trade restrictiveness" refers to the
restricting of trade flows, and not to the concept of discrimination,[71] it does not explicitly
exclude qualitative impacts on trade from being taken into account, along with quantitative
ones, in the analysis of "trade restrictiveness."[72]
17. Japan does not see a basis
for excluding discrimination from the scope of the analysis of trade
restrictiveness under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement. The text of Article 2.2
prohibits WTO Members from creating "unnecessary obstacles to
international trade". In Japan's view, this language suggests a broad
scope of application and it supports the conclusion that Article 2.2
imposes a prohibition on a range of activities that are broader than the direct
denial of market access.
18. The United States
highlights the separate obligations set out by Articles 2.1 and 2.2 and on
this basis argues that the term "trade restrictiveness" does not
refer to the concept of discrimination. Japan notes, in this regard, that Article 2.1
addresses whether a technical regulation has a detrimental impact on imported
products, whereas Article 2.2 examines the degree of impact that it has on
trade.
19. In its third party
submission, the European Union raises the question of whether the concept of
trade-restrictiveness is merely concerned with the absolute
impact of a regulation on imports, or also with its relative
impact on imported and domestic products.[73] Japan observes that none
of the parties, not even the United States as the respondent, seems to
confine "a limiting effect on trade" to the absolute impact of a
regulation on imports.
20. Japan turns now to the role
of "reasonably available alternative measures" in the Article 2.2.
Japan recalls that except for the two extreme instances mentioned by the
Appellate Body in US-Tuna
II (Mexico) where the challenged measure is either
not trade restrictive or makes no contribution at all to achieving the relevant
legitimate objective, a comparison between the trade-restrictiveness of the
technical regulation at issue and that of an alternative measures is required
under Article 2.2.
21. The comparison with
alternative measures is a fundamental element of the analysis of
trade-restrictiveness under Article 2.2. The objective of this comparison
is to determine whether there is an alternative measure that has a lower impact
on trade, or is more neutral as regards the competitive opportunities of the
imported products in the relevant market, than the challenged measure. In this
assessment, the removal of disproportionate compliance costs on imported
products would certainly have the effect of facilitating trade. In other
circumstances, depending on the absolute and relative costs that it imposes on
imported products, a non-discriminatory measure can have a more limiting effect
on trade than a discriminatory measure. Japan considers that this lends further
support to the conclusion that the term "trade restrictive" addresses
a broad range of impacts on trade including, but not limited to, the
modification in the competitive conditions of imported products.
22. With regard to the
allocation of the burden of proof under Article 2.2, Mexico contends that
a complaining party's burden is to simply "identify possible alternatives",
and that the complaining party does not have the burden of presenting evidence
and arguments sufficient to demonstrate that the alternative measure is less
trade restrictive, makes an equivalent contribution to the relevant objective
pursued and is reasonably available.[74] As explained by the
Appellate Body, and as argued in this case by the United States in detail,[75] Japan believes that a
complaining party bears the burden of presenting a prima facie case
that the challenged measure is inconsistent with Article 2.2 by
establishing that there is an alternative measure reasonably available and that
this alternative measure is less trade restrictive and makes an equivalent
contribution to the relevant objective pursued.
ANNEX
C-7
integrated
executive summary of the arguments
of the republic of korea*
1. The Republic of Korea ("Korea") appreciates this opportunity to
present its views to the Panel as a third party. The decision
of this Panel will provide
important guidelines to the WTO Members
in making their policy decisions and formulating their respective government programs in a manner consistent with the relevant rules of the
WTO.
2. While the parties to the dispute and third
parties raise several important issues, Korea would like to briefly focus on
certain systemic issues. First, Korea would like to share its views about what
kind of legal standard must be established with respect to the Article 21.5
panel's terms of reference. Second, Korea would like to comment on whether the
trace-back system suggested by the complaints can be a reasonably available
alternative measure consistent with Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
COMPLIANCE PANEL SHOULD BEAR IN MIND ‘TRUE
FINALITY' OF A DISPUTE IN DETERMINING ITS TERMS OF REFERENCE
3. To begin with, Korea observes that compliance panel's
jurisdiction has become an important systemic issue in the recent Article 21.5
proceedings. As the number of compliance disputes
increases,[76] the scope of compliance panel's terms of reference has also been in dispute as a major systemic issue.
4. Korea has maintained that a compliance panel
must possess a relatively broad authority to identify measures taken to comply.
The Appellate Body in several Article 21.5 disputes has ruled that
measures taken to comply are not confined to the declared measures by the
implementing Member.[77] The Appellate Body in Mexico –
Corn Syrup (Article 21.5) has particularly ruled that panels
have a duty to examine issues of a "fundamental nature," issues that
go to the root of their jurisdiction on their own motion even if the parties to
the dispute remain silent on those issues.[78]
5. Because the WTO jurisprudence recognizes a
compliance panel's broad authority to identify measures to comply, Korea
believes that certain guiding principle to determine whether a measure is
within a compliance panel's jurisdiction would be necessary. As a guiding
principle to determine compliance panel's jurisdiction, Korea submits that the
concept of ‘true finality' may assist a compliance panel in delineating its
jurisdiction. As we understand, ‘true finality' of a dispute could be achieved
when a compliance panel resolves all the disagreements between the parties to
the dispute with respect to measures taken to comply. As a practical matter,
true finality of a dispute should envisage a situation where the exporters of
the aggrieved party restore their competitiveness which they had enjoyed before
the WTO inconsistent measures imposed by the Member concerned.
6. It should be noted, however, that the concept of ‘true
finality' should not be interpreted to include all the claims raised by the complaining party. As Korea has pointed out, if a compliance panel's terms of reference are
overly broad, it may open a possibility for the parties to the dispute to
re-litigate the issues already lost in the prior proceedings. Therefore, compliance
panel must strike a balance between the broad authority and the concerns on
re-litigation.
7. In this respect, Korea would like to briefly
comment on certain aspects of the principle of res judicata,
although the principle is known to be inapplicable to international law. The
principle of res judicata precludes parties
from re-litigating claims that have already been finally resolved in a prior
proceeding before a competent tribunal. Of course, the narrow scope of the WTO
panel's terms of reference must be distinguished from the more flexible municipal
court proceedings where the principle of res judiciata
applies. Ordinarily, in the municipal court proceedings, each party can amend
its complaint as necessary with permission by the court. As we know, this kind
of flexibility is not allowed in the WTO dispute settlement procedures. Nonetheless,
systemic interest in achieving finality of disputes still exists in the WTO
dispute settlement procedures.
8. For example, the Panel in India-Autos examined certain
aspect of res judicata. In that dispute, India
argued that certain import licensing requirements that were the subject of the
dispute had already been addressed by a prior WTO proceeding, and therefore
should not be considered by the panel in the subsequent proceeding. Although
the Panel did not directly touched upon the issue of res judicata,
it appeared to take the position that res judicata
would apply to the issues that were actually litigated and decided in the prior
WTO dispute.[79]
PANEL SHOULD EXAMINE WHETHER THE POLICY
OBJECTIVE OF THE TRACE-BACK SYSTEM WOULD BE DIFFERENT FROM THE POLICY OBJECTIVE
THAT THE COOL REQUIREMENTS PURSUE
9. One of the issues in this compliance
proceeding is whether trace-back system suggested by the complaints as a reasonably
available alternative measure is congruent with the object and purpose under Article 2.2
of the TBT Agreement. It seems to be agreed among the parties to this
dispute that the trace-back system will apply to both domestic and imported
product in a non-discriminatory manner. However, the parties disagree on the
question of whether the trace-back system requiring more burden on the farms
and meat producers is permissible as a reasonably available alternative measure
under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement.
10. To Korea's understanding, the ordinary
meaning of trade-restrictiveness would be that the flow of goods and services
between national borders is constrained. Considering the additional costs and
administrative burden incurred by the trace-back system, one would tend to
conclude that the alternative measure would constrain the flow of the goods in
dispute. Therefore, without legitimate policy objective justifying the
additional burden, the trace-back system would not seem to be a reasonably available
alternative measure.
11. In this dispute, the objective of the COOL
requirements is clear: that is, to provide consumers of certain designated
products with information about country of origin in order to enhance the
consumers' right to know. Clearly, the trace-back system seems to meet this
policy objective. However, a question arises as to reasonableness of the
measure. In other words, is the trace-back system reasonably available
alternative measure to substitute for the current COOL requirement?
12. To Korea's understanding, there exist
somewhat different policy objectives between the COOL requirements and the
trace-back system. Normally, a trace-back system is known to be adopted to
ensure animal health and food safety. That being said, the policy objective of
the trace-back system would be surveillance rather than consumers' right to
know. Therefore, this Panel should examine whether the degree of information
required in the trace-back system is appropriate and necessary to fulfill the
policy objective, contemplated in the COOL requirements. If the trade-back
system incurring additional costs and administrative burden unnecessarily
requires more information than the policy objective of the COOL requirements
pursues, Korea considers that the trace-back system should not be regarded as a
reasonably available alternative
measure.
13. This concludes Korea's oral statement. Again,
Korea appreciates this opportunity to present its view and would be happy to
take questions you might have.
ANNEX
C-8
integrated
executive summary of the arguments of new zealand
I. INTRODUCTION
1. New Zealand's
participation as a Third Party in this dispute reflects both its systemic legal
issues arising from the amended country of origin labelling measure and its
trade interest in the United States beef market.
II. THE
DISPUTE SETTLEMENT UNDERSTANDING
2. New Zealand notes that
the United States' amended Country of Origin Labeling Measure[80] (amended COOL measure)
was subject to a six month "education and outreach" grace period in
which it was legally in force, but was not fully enforced to allow retailers
and suppliers transition to the new rule.[81] Article 21.1 of
the Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes
(DSU) provides that prompt compliance with the recommendations and rulings of
the Dispute Settlement Body is essential in the effective resolution of
disputes. If compliance were achieved once a Member formally changed the law on
its books, even where the Member has stated its intention not to fully
implement it until a later date, relief for Members suffering adverse effects
from a non-compliant measure would be deferred until this later date. This
would have systemic implications for the dispute settlement process.
New Zealand approves of the approach taken in previous disputes where the
appropriateness and length of a grace period was considered in a determination
as to the "reasonable period of time" for compliance under Article 21.3(c)
of the DSU.[82]
III. THE AGREEMENT ON TECHNICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE
A. ARTICLE 2.1: THE FRAMEWORK TO ASSESS
LEGITIMATE REGULATORY DISTINCTIONS
3. The Appellate Body has stated that a technical regulation that detrimentally impacts on
imported products compared to like domestic products will nevertheless be
consistent with Article 2.1 of the Agreement on Technical Barriers to
Trade (TBT Agreement) if this impact stems from a legitimate regulatory
distinction.[83] Jurisprudence further
clarifies that a regulatory distinction that is not designed in an even-handed
manner will not be legitimate.[84] A regulatory distinction
will not be even-handed if it is designed or applied in a manner that "constitutes
a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination".[85]
4. The recently published panel report in EC – Seal Products may provide a useful framework for the
Panel to consider in assessing the exceptions and flexibilities in the amended
COOL measure.[86] The Panel's approach in EC – Seal Products involves
consideration of three questions: First, is the regulatory distinction
rationally connected to the objective of the overarching measure? Second, if
not, is there any cause or rationale that can justify the distinction (i.e., "explain
the existence of the distinction") despite the absence of the connection
to the objective of the overarching measure, taking into account the particular
circumstances of the instant dispute? Third, is the distinction "designed
or applied in a manner that constitutes arbitrary or unjustifiable
discrimination" such that it lacks "even-handedness"?[87]
5. If this analysis concludes that individual
regulatory distinctions are even-handed, New Zealand submits that a Panel
should also step back to consider the measure as a whole in determining whether
there is less favourable treatment. This additional step would prevent Members
from expressly designing measures with even-handed regulatory distinctions
that, when combined, nevertheless have an overall protectionist effect. While
individual distinctions may be even-handed, the number and/or nature of the
distinctions may still accord less favourable treatment to like imported
products.
B. ARTICLE 2.2: DETERMINING WHETHER A
MEASURE IS MORE TRADE-RESTRICTIVE THAN NECESSARY
(i) It is not necessary to add the relative
importance of the common interests or values as a separate factor to the
Appellate Body's test
6. The Appellate Body has set
out a test for assessing whether a technical regulation is "more
trade-restrictive than necessary" under Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement,
which involves consideration of three matters: (i) the degree of contribution
made by the measure to the legitimate objective at issue; (ii) the
trade-restrictiveness of the measure; and (iii) the nature of the risks at
issue and the gravity of consequences that would arise from non-fulfilment of
the objective(s) pursued by the Member through the measure.[88]
7. Mexico has suggested that "the
relative importance of the common interests or values furthered by the
challenged measure" should be added as an additional factor in the Article 2.2
necessity test.[89] While the importance of
the common interests or values at stake is an important element under Article 2.2,
this is already considered (albeit indirectly) in the assessment of the "nature
of the risks at issue and the gravity of the consequences that would arise from
non-fulfilment of the objective". To include the importance of the
objective as a separate factor could cause confusion, and may give the
importance of the objective (or the lack of importance) undue emphasis in the overall
weighing and balancing process.
8. New Zealand would be concerned if this
increased emphasis undermined the rights of WTO Members to decide which
legitimate policy objectives they wish to pursue, and the levels at which they
wish to pursue them.[90] Establishing the relative
importance of the objective as a factor in its own right would lead panels to
difficult assessments of the hierarchy of legitimate objectives.
New Zealand considers that, beyond objectives such as the protection of
human health that are universally recognised as being of utmost importance,
different Members will place importance on different objectives based on
current circumstances and their own subjective values and priorities, all of
which may change over time. New Zealand is therefore wary of any attempts
to categorise or rank the importance of legitimate objectives in advance, and
in isolation from the measure and the Member under consideration.
(ii) There must be a
balancing and weighing in the consideration of alternative measures
9. The Appellate Body in US – Tuna II (Mexico) found that the text of Article 2.2
imports an element of "weighing and balancing" into the analysis of
whether a technical regulation is more trade restrictive than necessary by
requiring the risks non-fulfilment of the objective would create to be taken
into account.[91] This process will
generally involve a comparative analysis of the challenged measure against
reasonably available alternatives.
10. This analysis requires the
Panel to identify the legitimate objective of the challenged measure in order
to assess the contribution it makes to that objective and to assess the risks
that non-fulfilment of that objective would create. The proper identification
of the legitimate objective is therefore fundamentally important to identify
these comparison points to evaluate against proposed alternatives. A legitimate
objective described in an artificially narrow manner may prevent the
formulation of reasonably available alternatives.
11. The parties differ as to the
comparative contribution that an alternative measure is required to make to the
achievement of the legitimate objective. New Zealand's view is that the
fact that an alternative measure makes a lesser contribution to the legitimate
objective is a highly relevant, but not determinative, factor in this weighing
and balancing process. The extent of this lesser contribution should be
balanced against the risks that non-fulfilment of the objective would create
and the trade-restrictiveness of the measure. For instance, an alternative
measure that makes only a slightly lesser contribution to the legitimate
objective, but is considerably less trade restrictive, may
demonstrate that a challenged measure is more trade restrictive than necessary
if the risks that non-fulfilment of the objective would create are not
particularly grave. However, New Zealand expects that an alternative
measure that makes a lesser contribution to the legitimate objective will only
very rarely demonstrate an inconsistency with Article 2.2.
12. In regard to possible
alternatives, New Zealand notes Mexico's and Canada's proposed first
alternative measure that includes a mandatory COOL requirement based on
substantial transformation, complemented by a voluntary COOL scheme that
provides information on where the animal was born, raised and slaughtered.[92] New Zealand
considers that voluntary COOL may be an alternative measure where there is no
health or safety objective behind the regulation. As noted by Mexico[93] and Canada,[94] voluntary COOL can
provide the same information to the consumer if there is consumer demand for
such information. Voluntary COOL allows the design and operation of a labelling
system to be developed in response to supply and demand needs. Well-designed
voluntary COOL can make an equivalent (or even better) contribution to the
objective of providing consumers with information as to origin than a mandatory
COOL regime that is peppered with exceptions.
IV.
THE GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE 1994
13. The complainants and
respondent differ as to the correct interpretation of the term "treatment
no less favourable" in Article III:4 of the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade 1994 (GATT 1994) as compared to the interpretation
of the same term in Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement. The Appellate
Body has found that Article III:4 of the GATT 1994 provides relevant
context for interpreting the term "treatment no less favourable in Article 2.1
of the TBT Agreement,[95] given the provisions
are "built around the same core terms, namely ‘like products' and
‘treatment no less favourable'".[96]
14. However, the legal standards
for the national treatment obligations are not identical. Article III:4 of
the GATT 1994 prohibits Members from modifying the conditions of
competition in the marketplace to the detriment of the group of imported
products vis-à-vis the group of domestic products.[97] In contrast, as noted
above at paragraph 3, the Appellate Body has consistently maintained that
the "treatment no less favourable" requirement in Article 2.1 of
the TBT Agreement does not prohibit "detrimental impact on imports
that stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction".[98] This additional element
in Article 2.1 reflects the context in which the term "treatment no
less favourable" is used, particularly the second, fifth and sixth
recitals of the preamble, the text of Article 2.2, the definition of "technical
regulation",[99] and the lack of a
general exceptions clause in the TBT Agreement.[100] The United States
submits[101] that analysis under Article III:4
requires an assessment of whether distinctions can be explained by factors or
circumstances unrelated to the origin of the imported product on the basis of
the Appellate Body reports in Dominican Republic –
Import and Sale of Cigarettes[102] and EC – Asbestos.[103] New Zealand notes
that the Appellate Body in US – Clove Cigarettes
specifically found that Dominican Republic –
Import and Sale of Cigarettes is not authority for the proposition
that panels should inquire further into whether the detrimental effect is
unrelated to the foreign origin of the product in an Article III:4
analysis.[104]
15. The jurisprudence therefore
provides that the analysis under Article III:4 of the GATT 1994
focuses on the modification of the conditions of competition in the
marketplace.[105] However,
New Zealand acknowledges the concern that this legal analysis could result
in a technical regulation being found consistent with the national treatment
obligation in Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement (because the
detrimental impact stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction)
but nevertheless inconsistent with Article III:4 of the GATT 1994
because the reason for the distinction does not fall within the general
exceptions in Article XX of the GATT 1994. New Zealand expresses
some unease about this potential outcome, particularly as the TBT Agreement
is the more specialised agreement dealing with technical regulations. That
being the case, the WTO-consistency or otherwise of a technical regulation
should primarily be determined by the Agreement negotiated specifically to
discipline such measures. This issue is unlikely to be resolved as a matter of
strict legal interpretation, and New Zealand supports the complainants'
view that the scope and content of the obligations in Article III:4 of the
GATT 1994 and Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement are distinct and
that "treatment no less favourable" under Article III:4 focuses
on the modification of the conditions of competition in the marketplace.[106]
__________
[1] These procedures are adopted according to, and are an integral part
of, the Panel's Working Procedures of 25 October 2013.
[2] These procedures are adopted according to, and are an integral part
of, the Panel's Working Procedures of 25 October 2013.
[3] These procedures are adopted according to, and are an integral part
of, the Panel's Working Procedures of 25 October 2013.
[4] These procedures are adopted according to, and are an integral part
of, the Panel's Working Procedures of 25 October 2013.
[5] US – Clove Cigarettes (Appellate
Body Report, para. 174)
[6] EC – Seal Products (Panel Report,
para. 7.278-7.278)
[7] US – COOL (AB Reports, paragraph 270).
Emphasis added.
[8] Korea – Various Measures on Beef (AB Report,
paragraph 164)
[9] US-Tuna II (Appellate Body Report
paragraph 321)
[10] Appellate Body Report, US – Softwood Lumber IV (Article 21.5
– Canada), para. 71.
[11] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 293.
[14] Canada's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 69.
[15] US's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 87.
[16] US's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 88.
[17] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 348.
[18] US's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 90.
[19] US's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 92.
[20] Mexico's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 153,
[21] Appellate Body Reports, US – COOL,
para. 378 (quoting Appellate Body Report, US – Tuna (II) Mexico, para. 322)
[22] Mexico's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 153,
[25] Mexico's
First Written Submission, US – COOL (21.5), para. 178,
[28] Panel
report, EC-Seal Products, para 7.467.
[29] AB Report, United States – certain country of origin labelling
(cool) requirements. WT/DS384/AB/R WT/DS386/AB/R, adopted 29 June 2012.
[30] According to the Oxford Dictionary definition.
[31] To elaborate on this concept's application, Colombia suggests to
consult Max Andenas and Stefan Zleptnig, Proportionality: Wto Law: In
Comparative Perspective Texas International Law Journal - Vol. 42 Num. 3, July
2007
[32] Supra Max Adenas and Stefan Zleptnig, p. 4
[33] Report of the Panel. United States – Measures Concerning the
Importation, Marketing and Sale of Tuna And Tuna Product. WT/DS381/R adopted15
September 2011. Para. 7.441
[34] AB. US – Gasoline, p. 28; Panel Report, US – Shrimp, para. 7.26,
Fn 629; GATT Panel Report, Japan – Alcoholic Beverages I, para. 5.13
* India's oral statement serves as the integrated executive summary.
[35] WT/DS257/AB/RW, paragraph 67-69. Also see Appellate Body report in US OCTG SSR (21.5), WT/DS268/AB/RW, paragraph 147
[36] WT/DS257/AB/RW, paragraph 71
[37] WT/DS70/AB/RW, paragraph 40-42
[38] US Shrimp (21.5), WT/DS58/AB/RW,
paragraph 87
[39] US Shrimp (21.5), WT/DS58/AB/RW,
paragraph 86-87
[40] WT/DS257/AB/RW, paragraph 71
[41] US Shrimp (21.5), WT/DS58/AB/RW,
paragraph 87
[42] WT/DS135/AB/R, paragraph 185
[43] WT/DS141/AB/RW, footnote 115 to para 96. Also see paragraph 14 of
the second written submission by Mexico.
[44] Canada's first written submission, para. 15; Mexico's first written
submission, para. 44.
[45] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL, para. 347.
[46] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 344.
[47] Canada's first written submission, para.18; Mexico's first written
submission, para.46.
[48] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 344, quoting Panel Report, US
– COOL, para. 7.417.
[49] United States' second written submission to the original
Panel, paras. 149, 153-154; see also Panel Report, US – COOL,
para. 7.711.
[50] United States' second written submission to the original
Panel, para.137.
[51] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 271, quoting Appellate Body
Report, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 182.
[52] Mexico's first written submission, para. 155.
[53] Appellate Body Report, US – Tuna II (Mexico),
footnote 647 to para. 322 (emphasis omitted).
[54] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 476.
[55] Canada's first written submission, para. 118 (emphasis omitted).
[56] Mexico's first written submission, para. 162.
[57] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 387.
[58] See Appellate Body Report, US – Brazil Retreated Tyres, para. 156 and Appellate Body
Report, US – Gambling, para. 308.
[59] Appellate
Body Report, US-Tuna (Mexico), para. 321; see also
Appellate Body Report, US – COOL,
para. 377.
[60] Appellate
Body Report, US – Tuna II (Mexico), para. 215 (referring to Appellate Body Report, US – Clove
Cigarettes, paras. 180 and 215).
[61] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL, para.
271.
[62] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
para. 182.
[63] Appellate Body Report, US – Tuna II (Mexico),
para. 215 (referring to Appellate Body Report, US – Clove
Cigarettes, paras. 180 and 215).
[64] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
para.88.
[65] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
para.96. See also Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
para.101.
[66] Appellate Body Report, EC – Asbestos,
paras. 113-116. See also Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes, paras.117-119.
[67] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
paras.116.
[68] Appellate
Body Report, Brazil – Tyres, para.227.
[69] Second Written Submission of Canada, para. 71.
[70] Second Written Submission of the United States of America,
para. 107.
[71] First Written Submission of United States of America, para.
153.
[72] See e.g., Second Written Submission of Canada, para. 71.
[73] European Union Third-Party Written Submission, para. 110.
[74] Second Written Submission of the United Mexican States, paras.
114-119.
[75] Second Written Submission of the United States of America,
paras. 114-119.
* The Republic of Korea requested that its oral statement serve as
the integrated executive summary.
[76] As of 16 February 2014, 48 complaints requesting Article 21.5
panel have been filed in the DSB since 1995. In the same period, 110 disputes
have been appealed. About half of the DSB decisions have not been effectively resolved,
resulting in compliance disputes. See the
statistics in www.worldtradelaw.net.
(last visited on 16 February 2014).
[77] E.g.,
Appellate Body
Reports, US-Softwood Lumber IV (Article 21.5
– Canada); US-Zeroing (Article 21.5
– EC).
[78] Appellate
Body Report, Mexico-Corn Syrup (Article 21.5),
para. 36, quoted in US-Countervailing Measures
on Certain EC Products (Article 21.5 – EC), para. 7.35.
[79] Panel
Report, India-Measures
Affecting the Automotive Sector, paras. 7.62-66.
[80] As set out in §1638 of the Agricultural Marketing Act
of 1946 (7 U.S.C. § 1638 (2012)) and the
COOL regulations (i.e. the Final Rule on
Mandatory Country of Origin Labeling of Beef, Pork, Lamb, Chicken, Goat
Meat, Wild and Farm-Raised Fish and Shellfish, Perishable Agricultural
Commodities, Peanuts, Pecans, Ginseng and Macadamia Nuts, 74 Fed.
Reg, 2658 (15 January 2009) as modified by the Final Rule on
Mandatory Country of Origin Labeling of Beef, Pork, Lamb, Chicken, Goat
Meat, Wild and Farm-Raised Fish and Shellfish, Perishable Agricultural
Commodities, Peanuts, Pecans, Ginseng and Macadamia Nuts, 78 Fed.
Reg, 31,367 (24 May 2013).
[81] Mexico First Written
Submission, 31 October 2013 (Mexico FWS), para. 51.
[83] Appellate Body Reports, United States – Measures Affecting the Production and Sale of
Clove Cigarettes, WT/DS406/AB/R, adopted 24 April 2012, para. 181 (US – Clove Cigarettes); United States –
Measures Concerning the Importation, Marketing and Sale of Tuna and Tuna
Products, WT/DS381/AB/R, adopted 13 June 2012, para 215 (US – Tuna II (Mexico)); United States –
Certain Country of Origin Labelling (COOL) Requirements,
WT/DS384/AB/R /WT/DS386/AB/R, adopted 23 July 2012 (US – COOL),
para. 271.
[84] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 182 and US – COOL,
para. 271.
[85] Appellate Body Report, US – COOL, para. 271.
[86] Panel Report, European Communities – Measures Prohibiting the Importation and
Marketing of Seal Products, WT/DS400/R WT/DS401/R and Add. 1,
circulated to WTO Members 25 November 2013 (appeal in progress), para. 7.259.
[87] Panel
Report, EC – Seal Products, para. 7.259.
[88] Appellate
Body Report, US – Tuna II (Mexico), para. 322.
[89] Mexico
FWS, paras. 156 - 157.
[90] As recognised in Article 2.2
and the sixth recital to the preamble of the TBT Agreement.
[91] Appellate
Body Report, US – Tuna II (Mexico),
para. 321.
[92] Mexico
FWS, paras. 182 – 191; Canada First Written Submission, 31 October 2013 (Canada
FWS), paras. 156 – 163.
[93] Mexico
FWS, para. 185.
[94] Canada
FWS, para. 158.
[95] Appellate
Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, paras. 100
and 180; US – Tuna II (Mexico), para. 214; US – COOL, para. 269.
[96] Appellate
Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 100.
[97] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 179; US – Tuna II
(Mexico), para 214 (citing Appellate Body Report, Korea – Measures Affecting Imports of Fresh, Chilled
and Frozen Beef, WT/DS161/AB/R, WT/DS169/AB/R, adopted 10 January
2001 (Korea – Various Measures on Beef), para.
137); US – COOL, para. 270.
[98] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, paras. 174 and 181; US – COOL,
para. 271; US – Tuna II (Mexico), para. 215.
[99] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, paras. 88-102 and 181-182; US – Tuna II (Mexico), paras. 211-213; US – COOL, para. 268.
[100] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes,
para. 101.
[101] United States First Written Submission, 26 November 2013, paras. 131 – 134.
[102] Appellate Body Report, Dominican Republic – Measures Affecting the
Importation and Internal Sale of Cigarettes, WT/DS302/AB/R, adopted 19 May
2005.
[103] Appellate Body Report, European Communities – Measures Affecting
Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products, WT/DS135/AB/R, adopted 5 April 2001.
[104] Appellate Body Report, US – Clove Cigarettes, footnote 372 at para. 180.
[105] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 179; US – Tuna II
(Mexico), para. 214 (citing Appellate Body Reports, Korea – Various Measures on Beef, para. 137); US – COOL, para. 270.
[106] Appellate Body Reports, US – Clove Cigarettes, para. 179; US – Tuna II (Mexico),
para. 214 (citing Appellate Body Reports, Korea – Various Measures on Beef, para. 137); US – COOL, para. 270.